1
PHILIP R. SELLINGER JONATHAN S. KANTER
United States Attorney Assistant Attorney General
By: J. ANDREW RUYMAN DOHA G. MEKKI
Assistant U.S. Attorney Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General
402 East State Street, Room 430 HETAL J. DOSHI
Trenton, NJ 08608 MICHAEL B. KADES
Telephone: 609-989-0563 Deputy Assistants Attorney General
By: JONATHAN LASKEN
Assistant Chief, Civil Conduct Task Force
United States Department of Justice
Antitrust Division
450 Fifth Street NW, Suite 8600
Washington, DC 20530
Telephone: 202-598-6517
IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF NEW JERSEY
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division
450 Fifth Street NW, Suite 8600
Washington, DC 20530
STATE OF NEW JERSEY
124 Halsey Street, 5th Floor
Newark, NJ 07102
STATE OF ARIZONA
2005 N. Central Avenue
Phoenix, AZ 85004
STATE OF CALIFORNIA
455 Golden Gate Avenue, Suite 11000
San Francisco, CA 94102
DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
400 6th Street NW, 10
th
Floor
Washington, DC 20001
STATE OF CONNECTICUT
165 Capitol Avenue
Hartford, CT 06106
STATE OF MAINE
6 State House Statio
n
No.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 1 of 88 PageID: 1
2
Augusta, ME 04333
STATE OF MICHIGAN
525 W Ottawa Street
Lansing, MI 48933
STATE OF MINNESOTA
445 Minnesota Street, Suite 1400
Saint Paul, MN 55101
STATE OF NEW HAMPSHIRE
33 Capitol Street
Concord, NH 03301
STATE OF NEW YORK
28 Liberty Street
New York, NY 10005
STATE OF NORTH DAKOTA
1720 Burlington Drive, Suite C
Bismarck, ND 58504
STATE OF OKLAHOMA
15 West 6th Street, Suite 1000
Tulsa, OK 74119
STATE OF OREGON
100 SW Market Street
Portland, OR 97201
STATE OF TENNESSEE
Post Office Box 20207
Nashville, TN 37202
STATE OF VERMONT
109 State Street
Montpelier, VT 05609
STATE OF WISCONSIN
Post Office Box 7857
Madison, WI 53707
Plaintiffs,
v.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 2 of 88 PageID: 2
3
APPLE INC.
One Apple Park Way
Cupertino, CA 95014
Defendant.
COMPLAINT
In 2010, a top Apple executive emailed Apple’s then-CEO about an ad for the new
Kindle e-reader. The ad began with a woman who was using her iPhone to buy and read books
on the Kindle app. She then switches to an Android smartphone and continues to read her books
using the same Kindle app. The executive wrote to Jobs: one “message that can’t be missed is
that it is easy to switch from iPhone to Android. Not fun to watch.” Jobs was clear in his
response: Apple would “force” developers to use its payment system to lock in both developers
and users on its platform. Over many years, Apple has repeatedly responded to competitive
threats like this one by making it harder or more expensive for its users and developers to leave
than by making it more attractive for them to stay.
For many years, Apple has built a dominant iPhone platform and ecosystem that has
driven the company’s astronomical valuation. At the same time, it has long understood that
disruptive technologies and innovative apps, products, and services threatened that dominance by
making users less reliant on the iPhone or making it easier to switch to a non-Apple
smartphone. Rather than respond to competitive threats by offering lower smartphone prices to
consumers or better monetization for developers, Apple would meet competitive threats by
imposing a series of shapeshifting rules and restrictions in its App Store guidelines and developer
agreements that would allow Apple to extract higher fees, thwart innovation, offer a less secure
or degraded user experience, and throttle competitive alternatives. It has deployed this playbook
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 3 of 88 PageID: 3
4
across many technologies, products, and services, including super apps, text messaging,
smartwatches, and digital wallets, among many others.
Apple’s conduct also stifles new paradigms that threaten Apple’s smartphone dominance,
including the cloud, which could make it easier for users to enjoy high-end functionality on a
lower priced smartphone—or make users device-agnostic altogether. As one Apple manager
recently observed, “Imagine buying a [expletive] Android for 25 bux at a garage sale and it
works fine . . . . And you have a solid cloud computing device. Imagine how many cases like
that there are.” Simply put, Apple feared the disintermediation of its iPhone platform and
undertook a course of conduct that locked in users and developers while protecting its profits.
Critically, Apple’s anticompetitive conduct not only limits competition in the smartphone
market, but also reverberates through the industries that are affected by these restrictions,
including financial services, fitness, gaming, social media, news media, entertainment, and more.
Unless Apple’s anticompetitive and exclusionary conduct is stopped, it will likely extend and
entrench its iPhone monopoly to other markets and parts of the economy. For example, Apple is
rapidly expanding its influence and growing its power in the automotive, content creation and
entertainment, and financial services industries–and often by doing so in exclusionary ways that
further reinforce and deepen the competitive moat around the iPhone.
This case is about freeing smartphone markets from Apple’s anticompetitive and
exclusionary conduct and restoring competition to lower smartphone prices for consumers,
reducing fees for developers, and preserving innovation for the future. The United States and the
States of New Jersey, Arizona, California, Connecticut, Maine, Michigan, Minnesota, New
Hampshire, New York, North Dakota, Oklahoma, Oregon, Tennessee, Vermont, Wisconsin, and
the District of Columbia, acting by and through their respective
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 4 of 88 PageID: 4
5
Attorneys General, bring this case to address Apple’s anticompetitive and exclusionary conduct
and alleviate harm to competition.
I. Introduction
1. The Apple Computer Company, as it was then called, was founded in 1976 to
make and market personal computers. From its inception, Apple had a knack for expensive,
high-end design and niche marketing relative to its competitors. But it struggled to compete
against rivals that offered lower prices and more programs. After two decades, Apple struggled
to compete against Windows personal computers and by the late 1990s, it was on the brink of
bankruptcy.
2. Apple’s fortunes changed around the time it launched the iPod in 2001.
Innovative design and savvy marketing had not been enough to drive a successful business
strategy. This time, the confluence of several factors made it a smash success. Apple’s iTunes
application allowed iPod users to organize their song library and update their iPod. A path-
clearing antitrust enforcement case, brought by the United States and state attorneys general,
against Microsoft opened the market and constrained Microsoft’s ability to prohibit companies
like Apple from offering iTunes on Windows PCs. Licensing agreements with the major music
labels allowed Apple to offer iPod/iTunes users a wide selection of music for a fee-per-
download. The iPod experience gave Apple a recipe for the future: a high-end device, a large
number of platform participants (i.e., music labels and consumers), and a digital storefront. More
importantly, it gave Apple a playbook: drive as many consumers and third-party participants to
the platform as possible and offer a wide selection of content, products, and services created by
those third parties to consumers. This structure put Apple in the driver’s seat to generate
substantial revenues through device sales in the first instance and subsequently the ancillary fees
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 5 of 88 PageID: 5
6
that it derives from sitting between consumers on the one hand and the products and services
they love on the other.
3. Apple’s experience with the iPod set the stage for Apple’s most successful
product yet. In 2007, Apple launched the iPhone, a smartphone that offered high-end hardware
and software applications, called “apps,” built atop a mobile operating system that mimicked the
functionality and ease of use of a computer. Apple initially offered only a small number of apps
that it created for the iPhone. But Apple quickly realized the enormous value that a broader
community of entrepreneurial, innovative developers could drive to its users and the iPhone
platform more broadly. So Apple invited and capitalized on the work of these third parties while
maintaining control and monetizing that work for itself. The value of third parties’ work served
an important purpose for Apple. Indeed, as early as 2010, then-CEO Steve Jobs discussed how to
“further lock customers into our ecosystem” and “make Apple[’s] ecosystem even more sticky.”
Three years later, Apple executives were still strategizing how to “get people hooked to the
ecosystem.”
4. That strategy paid off. Over more than 15 years, Apple has built and sustained the
most dominant smartphone platform and ecosystem in the United States by attracting third-party
developers of all kinds to create apps that users could download on their smartphones through a
digital storefront called the App Store. As developers created more and better products, content,
apps, and services, more people bought iPhones, which incentivized even more third parties to
develop apps for the iPhone. Today, the iPhone’s ecosystem includes products, apps, content,
accessories, and services that are offered by content creators, newspaper publishers, banks,
advertisers, social media companies, airlines, productivity developers, retailers and other
merchants, and others. As Apple’s power grew, its leverage over third parties reinforced its tight
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 6 of 88 PageID: 6
7
control over how third parties innovate and monetize on and off the smartphone in ways that
were anticompetitive and exclusionary.
5. Today, Apple charges as much as $1,599 for an iPhone and earns high margins on
each one, more than double those of others in the industry. When developers imagine a new
product or service for iPhone consumers, Apple demands up to 30 percent of the price of an app
whose content, product, or service it did not create. Then when a consumer wants to buy some
additional service within that app, Apple extracts up to another 30 percent, again for a service
Apple does not create or develop. When customers buy a coffee or pay for groceries, Apple
charges a fee for every “tap-to-pay” transaction, imposing its own form of an interchange fee on
banks and a significant new cost for using credit cards. When users run an internet search,
Google gives Apple a significant cut of the advertising revenue that an iPhone user’s searches
generate.
6. Apple keenly understands that while a community of developers and accessory
makers is indispensable to the success of the iPhone, they also pose an existential threat to its
extraordinary profits by empowering consumers to “think different” and choose perfectly
functional, less-expensive alternative smartphones.
7. Apple’s smartphone business model, at its core, is one that invites as many
participants, including iPhone users and third-party developers, to join its platform as possible
while using contractual terms to force these participants to pay substantial fees. At the same
time, Apple restricts its platform participants’ ability to negotiate or compete down its fees
through alternative app stores, in-app payment processors, and more.
8. In order to protect that model, Apple reduces competition in the markets for
performance smartphones and smartphones generally. It does this by delaying, degrading, or
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 7 of 88 PageID: 7
8
outright blocking technologies that would increase competition in the smartphone markets by
decreasing barriers to switching to another smartphone, among other things. The suppressed
technologies would provide a high-quality user experience on any smartphone, which would, in
turn, require smartphones to compete on their merits.
9. Apple suppresses such innovation through a web of contractual restrictions that it
selectively enforces through its control of app distribution and its “app review” process, as well
as by denying access to key points of connection between apps and the iPhone’s operating
system (called Application Programming Interfaces or “APIs”). Apple can enforce these
restrictions due to its position as an intermediary between product creators such as developers on
the one hand and users on the other.
10. This complaint highlights five examples of Apple using these mechanisms to
suppress technologies that would have increased competition among smartphones. Suppressing
these technologies does not reflect competition on the merits. Rather, to protect its smartphone
monopoly—and the extraordinary profits that monopoly generates—Apple repeatedly chooses to
make its products worse for consumers to prevent competition from emerging. These examples
below individually and collectively have contributed to Apple’s ability to secure, grow, and
maintain its smartphone monopoly by increasing switching costs for users, which leads to higher
prices and less innovation for users and developers. Apple has used one or both mechanisms
(control of app distribution or control of APIs) to suppress the following technologies, among
others:
Super apps provide a user with broad functionality in a single app. Super apps can
improve smartphone competition by providing a consistent user experience that can
be ported across devices. Suppressing super apps harms all smartphone users—
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 8 of 88 PageID: 8
9
including Apple users—by denying them access to high quality experiences and it
harms developers by preventing them from innovating and selling products.
Cloud streaming game apps provide users with a way to play computing intensive
games in the cloud. Cloud streaming games (and cloud streaming in general) can
improve smartphone competition by decreasing the importance of expensive
hardware for accomplishing high compute tasks on a smartphone. Suppressing cloud
streaming games harms users by denying them the ability to play high-compute
games, and it harms developers by preventing them from selling such games to users.
Messaging apps are apps that allow users to communicate with friends, family, and
other contacts. Messaging apps that work equally well across all smartphones can
improve competition among smartphones by allowing users to switch phones without
changing the way they communicate with friends, family, and others. Apple makes
third-party messaging apps on the iPhone worse generally and relative to Apple
Messages, Apple’s own messaging app, by prohibiting third-party apps from sending
or receiving carrier-based messages. By doing so, Apple is knowingly and
deliberately degrading quality, privacy, and security for its users and others who do
not have iPhones. Apple also harms developers by artificially constraining the size of
their user base.
Smartwatches are an expensive accessory that typically must be paired to a
smartphone. Smartwatches that can be paired with different smartphones allow users
to retain their investment in a smartwatch when switching phones thereby decreasing
the literal cost associated with switching from one smartphone to another, among
other things. By suppressing key functions of third-party smartwatches—including
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 9 of 88 PageID: 9
10
the ability to respond to notifications and messages and to maintain consistent
connections with the iPhone—Apple has denied users access to high performing
smartwatches with preferred styling, better user interfaces and services, or better
batteries, and it has harmed smartwatch developers by decreasing their ability to
innovate and sell products.
Digital wallets are an increasingly important way that smartphones are used and are a
product in which users develop a great deal of comfort and trust as they typically
contain users’ most sensitive information. Digital wallets that work across
smartphone platforms allow users to move from one smartphone brand to another
with decreased frictions, among other things. Apple has denied users access to digital
wallets that would have provided a wide variety of enhanced features and denied
digital wallet developers—often banks—the opportunity to provide advanced digital
payments services to their own customers.
11. By maintaining its monopoly over smartphones, Apple is able to harm consumers
in a wide variety of additional ways. For example, by denying iPhone users the ability to choose
their trusted banking apps as their digital wallet, Apple retains full control both over the
consumer and also over the stream of income generated by forcing users to use only Apple-
authorized products in the digital wallet. Apple also prohibits the creation and use of alternative
app stores curated to reflect a consumer’s preferences with respect to security, privacy, or other
values. These and many other features would be beneficial to consumers and empower them to
make choices about what smartphone to buy and what apps and products to patronize. But
allowing consumers to make that choice is an obstacle to Apple’s ability to maintain its
monopoly.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 10 of 88 PageID: 10
11
12. Of course, this is not the story Apple presents to the world. For decades, Apple
branded itself a nimble, innovative upstart. In 1998, Apple co-founder Steve Jobs criticized
Microsoft’s monopoly and “dirty tactics” in operating systems to target Apple, which prompted
the company “to go to the Department of Justice” in hopes of getting Microsoft “to play fair.”
But even at that time, Apple did not face the same types of restrictions it imposes on third parties
today; Apple users could use their iPod with a Windows computer, and Microsoft did not charge
Apple a 30 percent fee for each song downloaded from Apple’s iTunes store. Similarly, when
Apple brought the iPhone to market in 2007, it benefited from competition among component
makers and wireless carriers.
13. While Apple’s anticompetitive conduct arguably has benefited its shareholders—
to the tune of over $77 billion in stock buybacks in its 2023 fiscal year alone—it comes at a great
cost to consumers. Some of those costs are immediate and obvious, and they directly affect
Apple’s own customers: Apple inflates the price for buying and using iPhones while preventing
the development of features like alternative app stores, innovative super apps, cloud-streaming
games, and secure texting.
14. Other costs of Apple’s anticompetitive conduct may be less obvious in the
immediate term. But they are no less harmful and even more widespread, affecting all
smartphone consumers. Apple’s smartphone monopoly means that it is not economically viable
to invest in building some apps, like digital wallets, because they cannot reach iPhone users. This
means that innovations fueled by an interest in building the best, most user-focused product that
would exist in a more competitive market never get off the ground. What’s more, Apple itself
has less incentive to innovate because it has insulated itself from competition. As Apple’s
executives openly acknowledge: “In looking at it with hindsight, I think going forward we need
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 11 of 88 PageID: 11
12
to set a stake in the ground for what features we think are ‘good enough’ for the consumer. I
would argue we’re already doing *more* than what would have been good enough. But we find
it very hard to regress our product features YOY [year over year].” Existing features “would
have been good enough today if we hadn’t introduced [them] already,” and “anything new
and especially expensive needs to be rigorously challenged before it’s allowed into the consumer
phone.” Thus, it is not surprising that Apple spent more than twice as much on stock buybacks
and dividends as it did on research and development.
15. Moreover, Apple has demonstrated its ability to use its smartphone monopoly to
impose fee structures and manipulate app review to inhibit aggrieved parties from taking
advantage of regulatory and judicial solutions imposed on Apple that attempt to narrowly
remedy harm from its conduct.
16. Apple wraps itself in a cloak of privacy, security, and consumer preferences to
justify its anticompetitive conduct. Indeed, it spends billions on marketing and branding to
promote the self-serving premise that only Apple can safeguard consumers’ privacy and security
interests. Apple selectively compromises privacy and security interests when doing so is in
Apple’s own financial interest—such as degrading the security of text messages, offering
governments and certain companies the chance to access more private and secure versions of app
stores, or accepting billions of dollars each year for choosing Google as its default search engine
when more private options are available. In the end, Apple deploys privacy and security
justifications as an elastic shield that can stretch or contract to serve Apple’s financial and
business interests.
17. Smartphones have so revolutionized American life that it can be hard to imagine a
world beyond the one that Apple, a self-interested monopolist, deems “good enough.” But under
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 12 of 88 PageID: 12
13
our system of antitrust laws, “good enough” is, quite simply, not enough. Consumers,
competition, and the competitive process—not Apple alone—should decide what options
consumers should have. And competition, not Apple’s self-interested business strategies, should
be the catalyst for innovation essential to our daily lives, not only in the smartphone market but
in closely related industries like personal entertainment, automotive infotainment, and even more
innovations that have not yet been imagined. Competition is what will ensure that Apple’s
conduct and business decisions do not thwart the next Apple.
18. Protecting competition and the innovation that competition inevitably ushers in
for consumers, developers, publishers, content creators, and device manufacturers is why
Plaintiffs bring this lawsuit under Section 2 of the Sherman Act to challenge Apple’s
maintenance of its monopoly over smartphone markets, which affect hundreds of millions of
Americans every day. Plaintiffs bring this case to rid smartphone markets of Apple’s
monopolization and exclusionary conduct and to ensure that the next generation of innovators
can upend the technological world as we know it with new and transformative technologies.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 13 of 88 PageID: 13
14
TABLE OF CONTENTS
I. Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 5
II. Defendant Apple ............................................................................................................... 16
A. Apple launched the iPod, iTunes, and the iTunes Store against the backdrop of
United States v. Microsoft ..................................................................................... 18
B. Apple invited third-party investment on the iPhone and then imposed tight
controls on app creation and app distribution ....................................................... 21
III. Smartphones Are Platforms .............................................................................................. 24
IV. Apple Unlawfully Maintains Its Monopoly Power ........................................................... 26
A. Apple harms competition by imposing contractual restrictions, fees, and taxes on
app creation and distribution ................................................................................. 26
i. Super Apps: Apple prevented apps from threatening its smartphone
monopoly by undermining mini programs that reduce user dependence on
the iPhone.................................................................................................. 29
ii. Cloud Streaming Apps: Apple prevented developers from offering cloud
gaming apps that reduce dependence on the iPhone’s expensive hardware
................................................................................................................... 32
B. Apple uses APIs and other critical access points in the smartphone ecosystem to
control the behavior and innovation of third parties in order to insulate itself from
competition ........................................................................................................... 35
i. Messaging: Apple protects its smartphone monopoly by degrading and
undermining cross-platform messaging apps and rival smartphones ....... 35
ii. Smartwatches: Apple protects its smartphone monopoly by impeding the
development of cross-platform smartwatches .......................................... 39
iii. Digital Wallets: Apple restricts cross-platform digital wallets on the
iPhone, reinforcing barriers to consumers switching to rival smartphones
................................................................................................................... 42
C. Apple’s “moat” around its smartphone monopoly is wide and deep: it uses a
similar playbook to maintain its monopoly through many other products and
services .................................................................................................................. 46
V. Anticompetitive Effects .................................................................................................... 49
A. Apple’s conduct harms the competitive process ................................................... 49
B. Apple has every incentive to use its monopoly playbook in the future ................ 54
VI. Privacy, Security, and Other Alleged Countervailing Factors Do Not Justify Apple’s
Anticompetitive Conduct .................................................................................................. 55
VII. The Smartphone Industry .................................................................................................. 57
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 14 of 88 PageID: 14
15
A. Background ........................................................................................................... 57
B. Smartphone Hardware .......................................................................................... 58
C. Smartphone Operating Systems, Applications, and Other Software .................... 60
D. Relevant Markets .................................................................................................. 62
iv. Performance smartphones are a relevant product market ......................... 63
v. Smartphones are a broader relevant product market ................................. 64
vi. The United States is a relevant geographic market for performance
smartphones and smartphones .................................................................. 65
E. Apple has monopoly power in the smartphone and performance smartphone
markets .................................................................................................................. 66
VIII. Jurisdiction, Venue, and Commerce ................................................................................. 70
IX. Violations Alleged ............................................................................................................ 71
A. First Claim for Relief: Monopolization of the Performance Smartphone Market in
the United States in Violation of Sherman Act § 2 ............................................... 71
B. Second Claim for Relief, in the Alternative: Attempted Monopolization of the
Performance Smartphone Market in the United States in Violation of Sherman
Act § 2 ................................................................................................................... 72
C. Third Claim for Relief: Monopolization of the Smartphone Market in the United
States in Violation of Sherman Act § 2 ................................................................ 73
D. Fourth Claim for Relief, in the Alternative: Attempted Monopolization of the
Smartphone Market in the United States in Violation of Sherman Act § 2 .......... 74
E. Fifth Claim for Relief: Violation of the New Jersey Antitrust Act (Monopoly
Maintenance) ......................................................................................................... 75
F. Sixth Claim for Relief: Violations of Wisconsin State Law ................................. 76
X. Request for Relief ............................................................................................................. 76
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 15 of 88 PageID: 15
16
II. Defendant Apple
19. Apple is a global technology company with headquarters in Cupertino, California.
Apple is one of the world’s most valuable public companies with a market capitalization over
$2.5 trillion. In fiscal year 2023, Apple generated annual net revenues of $383 billion and net
income of $97 billion. Apple’s net income exceeds any other company in the Fortune 500 and
the gross domestic products of more than 100 countries.
20. The iPhone, Apple’s signature product, is the primary driver of Apple’s growth
and profitability, routinely commanding profit margins of more than 30 percent on devices
alone—significantly higher than its smartphone competitors. iPhone sales have made up a
majority of Apple’s annual revenue every year since 2012.
21. Apple increasingly extracts revenue from iPhone users beyond the initial
smartphone sale. For example, Apple offers iPhone upgrades, apps and in-app payments, paid
digital subscription services (e.g., Apple’s music streaming, TV, news, gaming, fitness, and
cloud storage subscriptions), accessories (e.g., tracking devices, headphones, chargers, iPhone
cases), and more. Apple refers to these offerings as “Services” and “Wearables, Home, and
Accessories,” respectively. In fiscal year 2023, these offerings accounted for nearly one-third of
Apple’s total revenue, or four times what Apple earned from selling Mac computers. Some of
the largest drivers of revenue within these categories are Apple’s smartwatch, the Apple Watch,
and Apple’s App Store, where iPhone users purchase and download apps. In recent years,
Services have accounted for an increasing share of Apple’s revenues, while the iPhone has
remained the primary gateway through which U.S. consumers access these services.
22. Apple’s U.S. market share by revenue is over 70 percent in the performance
smartphone market—a more expensive segment of the broader smartphone market where
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 16 of 88 PageID: 16
17
Apple’s own executives recognize the company competes—and over 65 percent for all
smartphones. These market shares have remained remarkably durable over the last decade.
23. Apple’s smartphone market shares understate Apple’s dominance and likely
growth in key demographics, including among younger American consumers. For example, one-
third of all iPhone users in the United States were born after 1996, as compared to just 10 percent
for Samsung, Apple’s closest smartphone competitor. Surveys show that as many as 88 percent
of U.S. teenagers expect to purchase an iPhone for their next smartphone. iPhone users also tend
to come from higher income households. Because smartphone users generally use a single
smartphone to access related products and services, locking up key user groups allows Apple to
capture greater spending on iPhone-related products and services, realize higher margins per user
as compared to its smartphone rivals, and exercise greater control over developers and other
smartphone ecosystem participants.
24. In fiscal year 2023, Apple spent $30 billion on research and development. By
comparison, Apple spent $77 billion on stock buybacks during the same year.
25. Apple was founded in 1976. During its first 25 years, the company focused in
large part on producing and marketing personal computers. Although the market for personal
computers expanded over the next several decades, Apple struggled to gain customer adoption
for its higher-priced products relative to its lower-cost competitors, including IBM and
Microsoft. In the late 1990s, Apple significantly restructured the company and embarked on a
new strategy focused not just on selling personal computers, but also consumer devices like the
iPod, which led to the development of the iPhone.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 17 of 88 PageID: 17
18
A. Apple launched the iPod, iTunes, and the iTunes Store against the backdrop
of United States v. Microsoft
26. When Apple began developing mobile consumer devices, it did so against the
backdrop of United States v. Microsoft, which created new opportunities for innovation in areas
that would become critical to the success of Apple’s consumer devices and the company itself.
For example, the iPod did not achieve widespread adoption until Apple developed a cross-
platform version of the iPod and iTunes for Microsoft’s Windows operating system, at the time
the dominant operating system for personal computers. In the absence of the consent decree in
United States v. Microsoft, it would have been more difficult for Apple to achieve this success
and ultimately launch the iPhone.
27. On May 18, 1998, the Justice Department and the attorneys general of 19 states
and the District of Columbia filed United States v. Microsoft, an antitrust lawsuit against
Microsoft alleging that the company had violated Section 2 of the Sherman Act by monopolizing
the market for Intel-compatible personal computer operating systems. At trial, the government
successfully established that Microsoft took steps to undermine the competitive threats posed by
“middleware,” such as web browsers like Netscape, after recognizing that if users could use
middleware to access a variety of content and services via remote servers, over the internet, they
might be less reliant on Windows.
28. Microsoft also took steps to undermine cross-platform technologies like
QuickTime, a software architecture developed by Apple to play multimedia content (e.g., music
and videos) on Apple’s Mac computers and Microsoft’s Windows PCs. In particular, Apple’s
then-Senior Vice President of Software Engineering testified that Microsoft “[wrote] steps into
its operating system to ensure that a QuickTime file will not operate reliably on Windows,”
“trick[ed] the user into believing that QuickTime technology is part of the problem actually
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 18 of 88 PageID: 18
19
caused by the Windows operating system,” and “introduced greater technical incompatibilities
between QuickTime and Microsoft products.”
29. In April 2000, the trial court ultimately found that Microsoft’s conduct violated
Section 2 of the Sherman Act. An appeals court upheld the district court’s findings of liability
regarding middleware.
30. In January 2001, Apple introduced iTunes, software built on Apple’s QuickTime
architecture, and advertised it as “Jukebox Software” for organizing and listening to music.
The initial version of iTunes was only compatible with Apple’s Mac computers.
31. Later that same year, Apple debuted the iPod, a portable digital audio player that
worked alongside iTunes to “let[] you put your entire music collection in your pocket and listen
to it wherever you go.” Like iTunes, the initial iPod was only compatible with Mac computers.
32. On November 1, 2002, the trial court accepted a proposed consent decree in
United States v. Microsoft. Among other things, the consent decree prohibited Microsoft from
retaliating against companies for developing or distributing products such as browsers and media
players. The consent decree also required Microsoft to make various APIs available to third-
party developers, including Apple.
33. Following that consent decree in October 2003, Apple launched a cross-platform
version of iTunes that was compatible with the Windows operating system. As a result, a much
larger group of users could finally use the iPod and iTunes, including the iTunes Store. The
iTunes Store allowed users to buy and download music and play it on their iTunes computer
application or on the iPod. Apple benefited substantially from this new customer base. In the first
two years after launching the iPod, Apple sold a few hundred thousand devices. The year after
launching a Windows-compatible version of iTunes and gaining access to millions more
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 19 of 88 PageID: 19
20
customers, Apple sold millions of devices. Apple went on to sell hundreds of millions of iPod
devices over the next two decades. Moreover, iTunes became the market leader in online music
services. At an event in 2007, Apple’s then-CEO said of the iPod, “it didn’t just change the way
we all listened to music, it changed the entire music industry.” At the same event, he announced
that the company would change its name from Apple Computer, Inc. to Apple, Inc. in light of its
shifting focus to consumer electronics rather than computers.
34. The ubiquity of iPod and iTunes on Windows, in part because of a successful
antitrust enforcement action against Microsoft, contributed to the development and success of
Apple’s next flagship product—the iPhone. But after launching the iPhone, Apple began stifling
the development of cross-platform technologies on the iPhone, just as Microsoft tried to stifle
cross-platform technologies on Windows.
35. In January 2007, Apple debuted the first-generation iPhone, describing the device
as “an iPod, a phone, and an internet communicator,” and touting the fact that users could
“sync[] content from a user’s iTunes library on their PC or Mac.” Apple marketed the iPhone as
a smartphone that was easy to use. Reflecting on the company’s learning from the iPod, Apple’s
then-CEO announced, “iTunes is going to sync all your media to your iPhone—but also a ton of
data. Contacts, calendars, photos, notes, bookmarks, email accounts.”
36. The original iPhone cost approximately $299—approximately $450 in 2024
dollars adjusted for inflation—with a two-year contract with a phone carrier.
37. At launch, nearly all native apps for the iPhone were created by Apple. There
were only about a dozen apps overall, including Calendar, Camera, Clock, Contacts, iPod,
Messages, Notes, Phone, Photos, Safari, Stocks, Voice Memos, and Weather.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 20 of 88 PageID: 20
21
38. Within a year of launching the iPhone, Apple invited third-party developers to
create native apps for the iPhone. Apple released its first software development kit—essentially
the digital tools for building native apps on Apple’s operating system (iOS)—to encourage and
enable third-party developers to create native apps for the iPhone. Apple also offered developers
ways to earn money by selling apps and later in-app purchases and subscriptions. By 2009,
Apple was running marketing campaigns highlighting the value that third-party apps provide to
iPhone users with the trademarked slogan: “There’s an app for that.”
39. Apple’s decision to invite third-party participation on its iPhone platform
benefited Apple, too. The proliferation of third-party apps generated billions of dollars in profits
for Apple and an iPhone user base of more than 250 million devices in the United States. Apple’s
market shares—over 70 percent of the performance smartphone market and over 65 percent of
the broader smartphone market—likely understate its monopoly power today.
40. While Apple profits from third-party developers that increase the iPhone’s value
to users, Apple executives understand that third-party products and services can, in their own
words, be “fundamentally disruptive” to its smartphone monopoly, decreasing users’ dependence
on Apple and the iPhone and increasing competitive pressure on Apple. Apple therefore
willingly sacrifices the short-term benefits it would gain from improved products and services
developed by third parties when necessary to maintain its monopoly.
B. Apple invited third-party investment on the iPhone and then imposed tight
controls on app creation and app distribution
41. Apple controls how developers distribute and create apps for iPhone users. For
example, developers can only distribute native iPhone apps through Apple’s App Store, which is
the only way for users to download native iOS apps. Limiting distribution to the Apple App
Store enables Apple to exert monopoly power over developers by imposing contractual
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 21 of 88 PageID: 21
22
restrictions and rules that limit the behavior of non-Apple apps and services. Specifically, Apple
sets the conditions for apps it allows on the Apple App Store through its App Store Review
Guidelines. Under these guidelines, Apple has sole discretion to review and approve all apps and
app updates. Apple selectively exercises that discretion to its own benefit, deviating from or
changing its guidelines when it suits Apple’s interests and allowing Apple executives to control
app reviews and decide whether to approve individual apps or updates. Apple often enforces its
App Store rules arbitrarily. And it frequently uses App Store rules and restrictions to penalize
and restrict developers that take advantage of technologies that threaten to disrupt,
disintermediate, compete with, or erode Apple’s monopoly power.
42. Apple also controls app creation by deciding which APIs are available to
developers when they make third-party apps. For example, developers cannot provide native
apps on the iPhone unless they enter into Apple’s non-negotiable Developer Program License
Agreement (DPLA). That agreement requires developers to use public APIs only “in the manner
prescribed by Apple.” It also prohibits third-party apps from using APIs that Apple designates as
“private.” Apple selectively designates APIs as public or private to benefit Apple, limiting the
functionality developers can offer to iPhone users even when the same functionality is available
in Apple’s own apps, or even select third-party apps. Similar to Apple’s App Store restrictions,
Apple uses its DPLA to impose restrictions that penalize and restrict developers that take
advantage of technologies that threaten to disrupt, disintermediate, compete with, or erode
Apple’s monopoly power.
43. Developers cannot avoid Apple’s control of app distribution and app creation by
making web apps—apps created using standard programming languages for web-based content
and available over the internet—as an alternative to native apps. Many iPhone users do not look
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 22 of 88 PageID: 22
23
for or know how to find web apps, causing web apps to constitute only a small fraction of app
usage. Apple recognizes that web apps are not a good alternative to native apps for developers.
As one Apple executive acknowledged, “[d]evelopers can’t make much money on the web.”
Regardless, Apple can still control the functionality of web apps because Apple requires all web
browsers on the iPhone to use WebKit, Apple’s browser engine—the key software components
that third-party browsers use to display web content.
44. Nor can developers rely on alternative app stores even though this would benefit
developers and users. For example, developers cannot offer iPhone users an app store that only
offers apps curated for use by children, which would provide opportunities to improve privacy,
security, and child safety. By contrast, Apple allows certain enterprise and public sector
customers to offer versions of app stores with more curated apps to better protect privacy and
security.
45. Apple’s control over both app distribution and app creation gives Apple
tremendous power. For example, Apple designates as “private” the APIs needed to send Short
Message Service, or SMS, text messages, which is a protocol used by mobile carriers since the
early 1990s to allow users to send basic text messages to other mobile phone numbers using their
own mobile phone numbers. Developers have no technical means to access these private APIs,
but even if they did, doing so would breach their developer agreement with Apple, and therefore
put the developer at risk of losing the ability to distribute apps through the App Store. For
example, Apple prohibits third-party iPhone apps from sending or receiving SMS text messages
even though this functionality is available through Apple Messages. Likewise, Apple can control
the functionality of third-party apps and accessories through its control of app distribution
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 23 of 88 PageID: 23
24
because if an app includes functionality that Apple does not like, Apple can and does exercise its
discretion to simply block the app from the App Store.
46. Apple’s dominance is such that neither app developers nor iPhone users can
benefit from lower cost or higher quality means of distributing apps or purchasing and providing
digital products and services. Instead, Apple guarantees that it continues to benefit from the
contributions of third-party developers and other platform participants while also protecting itself
from the competitive threats and pressure those participants pose to Apple’s smartphone
monopoly.
47. This complaint focuses on Apple’s use of its dominance to impose contracts and
rules that restrict the behavior and design decisions of companies other than Apple.
III. Smartphones Are Platforms
48. Smartphones combine the functionality of a traditional mobile phone with
advanced hardware and software components. This cluster of services and features results in a
distinct product for consumers and developers. For example, smartphones not only make phone
calls, but also allow users to listen to music, send text messages, take pictures, play games,
access software for work, manage their finances, and browse the internet.
49. Smartphones are platforms. Platforms bring together different groups that benefit
from each other’s participation on the platform. A food delivery app, for example, is a multi-
sided platform that brings together restaurants, couriers, and consumers. A two-sided platform,
for example, may bring together service providers on the one hand and consumers on the other.
The technology and economics of a smartphone platform are fundamentally different from the
technology and economics of a simultaneous transaction platform, such as a credit card, because
smartphone platforms compete over device features and pricing in ways that do not directly
relate to app store transactions. Whereas credit card transactions reflect a single simultaneous
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 24 of 88 PageID: 24
25
action that requires both sides of the transaction for either side to exist, consumers value
smartphone platforms for a variety of reasons separate from their ability to facilitate a
simultaneous transaction. Consumers care about non-transactional components of the phone,
such as its camera and processing speed, and they care about non-transactional components of
apps, such as their features and functionality.
50. The economics of a smartphone platform are such that the platform’s value to
users—and in turn to the platform operator—increase when new apps and new features are added
to the platform. In order to create these economic benefits for itself and its users, Apple has
opened its smartphone platform to third-party developers, whose countless inventions and
innovations have created enormous value. Apple has willingly opened the platform to third-party
developers to capture this value even though there is no extensive regulatory framework
requiring it to do so or overseeing how it interacts with those third parties. In this way,
smartphone platforms are very different from other platforms, like landline telephone networks,
whose value-adding features were built primarily by the platform operator and which were only
opened to third parties when the platform operator was required to do so by regulation. When a
third-party developer for the iPhone creates a valuable new feature, consumers benefit and
consumer demand goes up for Apple’s products, increasing the economic value of the iPhone to
Apple. This has played out hundreds of thousands of times for the iPhone, resulting in an
enormously valuable smartphone platform reflecting the combined contributions of millions of
developers.
51. In contrast, limiting the features and functionality created by third-party
developers—and therefore available to iPhone users—makes the iPhone worse and deprives
Apple of the economic value it would gain as the platform operator. It makes no economic sense
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 25 of 88 PageID: 25
26
for Apple to sacrifice the profits it would earn from new features and functionality unless it has
some other compensating reason to do so, such as protecting its monopoly profits.
IV. Apple Unlawfully Maintains Its Monopoly Power
A. Apple harms competition by imposing contractual restrictions, fees, and
taxes on app creation and distribution
52. Apple’s internal documents show that, soon after the iPhone’s introduction and
notwithstanding its success, the company began to fear that disintermediation of its platform and
the commoditization of the iPhone would threaten Apple’s substantial profits from iPhone sales
and related revenue streams.
53. Accordingly, Apple exercised its control of app creation and app distribution in
key cases to cement the iPhone and App Store as the primary gateway to apps, products, and
services. Apple often claims these rules and restrictions are necessary to protect user privacy or
security, but Apple’s documents tell a different story. In reality, Apple imposes certain
restrictions to benefit its bottom line by thwarting direct and disruptive competition for its iPhone
platform fees and/or for the importance of the iPhone platform itself.
54. Three aspects of Apple’s efforts to protect and exploit its smartphone monopoly
are worth noting. First, Apple exercises its control over app distribution and app creation to
dictate how developers innovate for the iPhone, enforcing rules and contractual restrictions
that stop or delay developers from innovating in ways that threaten Apple’s power. In so doing,
Apple influences the direction of innovation both on and off the iPhone.
55. Second, Apple drives iPhone users away from products and services that compete
with or threaten Apple. In doing so, Apple increases the cost and friction of switching from the
iPhone to another smartphone and generates extraordinary profits through subscription services
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 26 of 88 PageID: 26
27
(like Apple’s proprietary music, gaming, cloud storage, and news services), advertisements
within the App Store, and accessories like headphones and smartwatches.
56. Third, Apple uses these restrictions to extract monopoly rents from third parties in
a variety of ways, including app fees and revenue-share requirements. For most of the last 15
years, Apple collected a tax in the form of a 30 percent commission on the price of any app
downloaded from the App Store, a 30 percent tax on in-app purchases, and fees to access the
tools needed to develop iPhone native apps in the first place. While Apple has reduced the tax it
collects from a subset of developers, Apple still extracts 30 percent from many app makers.
Apple also generates substantial and increasing revenue by charging developers to help users
find their apps in the App Store—something that, for years, Apple told developers was part of
the reason they paid a 30 percent tax in the first place. For example, Apple will sell keyword
searches for an app to someone other than the owner of the app. Apple is able to command these
rents from companies of all sizes, including some of the largest and most sophisticated
companies in the world.
57. As Apple exercised its control of app distribution and app creation, Apple slowed
its own iPhone innovation and extracted more revenue and profit from its existing customers
through subscriptions, advertising, and cloud services. These services increase the cost of
switching from the iPhone to another smartphone because many of these services—including its
proprietary gaming, cloud storage, and news service—are exclusive to the Apple ecosystem,
causing significant frictions for iPhone users who try to use alternative services on another
smartphone. Moreover, Apple’s conduct demonstrates that Apple recognized the importance of
digital products and services for the success of the iPhone while at the same time it restricted the
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 27 of 88 PageID: 27
28
development and growth of non-iPhone products and services—especially those that might make
it easier for users to switch from the iPhone to another smartphone.
58. Each step in Apple’s course of conduct built and reinforced the moat around its
smartphone monopoly. The cumulative effect of this course of conduct has been to maintain and
entrench Apple’s smartphone monopoly at the expense of the users, developers, and other third
parties who helped make the iPhone what it is today. Despite major technological changes over
the years, Apple’s power to control app creation and distribution and extract fees from
developers has remained largely the same, unconstrained by competitive pressures or market
forces. That this conduct is impervious to competition reflects the success of Apple’s efforts to
create and maintain its smartphone monopoly, the strength of that monopoly, and the durability
of Apple’s power.
59. Apple’s monopoly maintenance has taken many forms and continues to evolve
today; however, Apple’s anticompetitive and exclusionary course of conduct is exemplified by
its contractual rules and restrictions targeting several products and services: super apps, cloud
streaming apps, messaging apps, smartwatches, and digital wallets. By stifling these
technologies, and many others, Apple reinforces the moat around its smartphone monopoly not
by making its products more attractive to users, but by discouraging innovation that threatens
Apple’s smartphone monopoly or the disintermediation of the iPhone. Apple continues to expand
and shift the scope and categories of anticompetitive conduct such that the cumulative
anticompetitive effect of Apple’s conduct is even more powerful than that of each exclusionary
act standing alone.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 28 of 88 PageID: 28
29
i. Super Apps: Apple prevented apps from threatening its smartphone
monopoly by undermining mini programs that reduce user
dependence on the iPhone
60. For years, Apple denied its users access to super apps because it viewed them as
“fundamentally disruptive” to “existing app distribution and development paradigms” and
ultimately Apple’s monopoly power. Apple feared super apps because it recognized that as they
become popular, “demand for iPhone is reduced.” So, Apple used its control over app
distribution and app creation to effectively prohibit developers from offering super apps instead
of competing on the merits.
61. A super app is an app that can serve as a platform for smaller “mini” programs
developed using programming languages such as HTML5 and JavaScript. By using
programming languages standard in most web pages, mini programs are cross platform, meaning
they work the same on any web browser and on any device. Developers can therefore write a
single mini program that works whether users have an iPhone or another smartphone.
62. Super apps can provide significant benefits to users. For example, a super app that
incorporates a multitude of mini programs might allow users to easily discover and access a wide
variety of content and services without setting up and logging into multiple apps, not unlike how
Netflix and Hulu allow users to find and watch thousands of movies and television shows in a
single app. As one Apple executive put it, “who doesn’t want faster, easier to discover apps that
do everything a full app does?” Restricting super apps makes users worse off and sacrifices the
short-term profitability of iPhones for Apple.
63. Super apps also reduce user dependence on the iPhone, including the iOS
operating system and Apple’s App Store. This is because a super app is a kind of middleware
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 29 of 88 PageID: 29
30
that can host apps, services, and experiences without requiring developers to use the iPhone’s
APIs or code.
64. As users interact with a super app, they rely less on the smartphone’s proprietary
software and more on the app itself. Eventually, users become more willing to choose a different
smartphone because they can access the same interface, apps, and content they desire on any
smartphone where the super app is also present. Moreover, developers can write mini programs
that run on the super app without having to write separate apps for iPhones and other
smartphones. This lowers barriers to entry for smartphone rivals, decreases Apple’s control over
third-party developers, and reduces switching costs.
65. Apple recognizes that super apps with mini programs would threaten its
monopoly. As one Apple manager put it, allowing super apps to become “the main gateway
where people play games, book a car, make payments, etc.” would “let the barbarians in at the
gate.” Why? Because when a super app offers popular mini programs, “iOS stickiness goes
down.”
66. Apple’s fear of super apps is based on first-hand experience with enormously
popular super apps in Asia. Apple does not want U.S. companies and U.S. users to benefit from
similar innovations. For example, in a Board of Directors presentation, Apple highlighted the
“[u]ndifferentiated user experience on [a] super platform” as a “major headwind” to growing
iPhone sales in countries with popular super apps due to the “[l]ow stickiness” and “[l]ow
switching cost.” For the same reasons, a super app created by a U.S. company would pose a
similar threat to Apple’s smartphone dominance in the United States. Apple noted as a risk in
2017 that a potential super app created by a specific U.S. company would “replace[ ] usage of
native OS and apps resulting in commoditization of smartphone hardware.”
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 30 of 88 PageID: 30
31
67. Apple did not respond to the risk that super apps might disrupt its monopoly by
innovating. Instead, Apple exerted its control over app distribution to stifle others’ innovation.
Apple created, strategically broadened, and aggressively enforced its App Store Guidelines to
effectively block apps from hosting mini programs. Apple’s conduct disincentivized investments
in mini program development and caused U.S. companies to abandon or limit support for the
technology in the United States.
68. In particular, part of what makes super apps valuable to consumers is that finding
and using mini programs is easier than using an app store and navigating many separate apps,
passwords, and set-up processes. Instead of making mini program discovery easy for users,
however, Apple made it nearly impossible.
69. Since at least 2017, Apple has arbitrarily imposed exclusionary requirements that
unnecessarily and unjustifiably restrict mini programs and super apps. For example, Apple
required apps in the United States to display mini programs using a flat, text-only list of mini
programs. Apple also banned displaying mini programs with icons or tiles, such as descriptive
pictures of the content or service offered by the mini program. Apple also banned apps from
categorizing mini programs, such as by displaying recently played games or more games by the
same developer. These restrictions throttle the popularity of mini programs and ultimately make
the iPhone worse because it discourages developers from creating apps and other content that
would be attractive to iPhone users.
70. Apple also selectively enforced its contractual rules with developers to prevent
developers from monetizing mini programs, hurting both users and developers. For example,
Apple blocked mini programs from accessing the APIs needed to implement Apple’s in-app
payment (IAP) system—even if developers were willing to pay Apple’s monopoly tax. Similarly,
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 31 of 88 PageID: 31
32
Apple blocked developers’ ability to use in-app payment methods other than directly using IAP.
For instance, super apps could create a virtual currency for consumers to use in mini programs,
but Apple blocked this too. Apple, however, allows other, less-threatening apps to do so.
ii. Cloud Streaming Apps: Apple prevented developers from offering
cloud gaming apps that reduce dependence on the iPhone’s expensive
hardware
71. For years, Apple blocked cloud gaming apps that would have given users access
to desirable apps and content without needing to pay for expensive Apple hardware because this
would threaten its monopoly power. In Apple’s own words, it feared a world where “all that
matters is who has the cheapest hardware” and consumers could “buy[] a [expletive] Android for
25 bux at a garage sale and . . . have a solid cloud computing device” that “works fine.” Apple’s
conduct made its own product worse because consumers missed out on apps and content. This
conduct also cost Apple substantial revenues from third-party developers. At the same time,
Apple also made other smartphones worse by stifling the growth of these cross-platform apps on
other smartphones. Importantly, Apple prevented the emergence of technologies that could lower
the price that consumers pay for iPhones.
72. Cloud streaming apps let users run a computationally intensive program without
having to process or store the program on the smartphone itself. Instead, a user’s smartphone
leverages the computing power of a remote server, which runs the program and streams the result
back to the phone. Cloud streaming allows developers to bring cutting-edge technologies and
services to smartphone consumers—including gaming and interactive artificial intelligence
services—even if their smartphone includes hardware that is less powerful than an iPhone.
73. Cloud streaming has significant benefits for users. For example, Apple has
promoted the iPhone 15 by promising that its hardware is powerful enough to enable “next-level
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 32 of 88 PageID: 32
33
performance and mobile gaming.” But powerful hardware is unnecessary if games are played via
cloud streaming apps. For a cloud game, the user experiences and plays the game on the
smartphone, but the game is run by hardware and software in remote computing centers (“the
cloud”). Thus, cloud gaming apps deliver rich gaming experiences on smartphones without the
need for users to purchase powerful, expensive hardware. As a result, users with access to cloud
streamed games may be more willing to switch from an iPhone to a smartphone with less
expensive hardware because both smartphones can run desirable games equally well.
74. Cloud streaming also has significant advantages for developers. For example,
instead of re-writing the same game for multiple operating systems, cloud platforms can act as
middleware that allow developers to create a single app that works across iOS, Android, and
other operating systems. Cloud streaming provides more and simpler options for offering
subscriptions, collecting payments, and distributing software updates as well. All of this helps
game developers reach economies of scale and profitability they might not achieve without
offering cloud gaming apps and reduces their dependence on iOS and Apple’s App Store.
75. Apple wielded its power over app distribution to effectively prevent third-party
developers from offering cloud gaming subscription services as a native app on the iPhone. Even
today, none are currently available on the iPhone.
76. For years, Apple imposed the onerous requirement that any cloud streaming
game—or any update to a cloud streaming game—be submitted as a stand-alone app for
approval by Apple. Having to submit individual cloud streaming games for review by Apple
increased the cost of releasing games on the iPhone and limited the number of games a developer
could make available to iPhone users. For example, the highest quality games, referred to as
AAA games, typically require daily or even hourly updates across different platforms. If these
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 33 of 88 PageID: 33
34
updates need to be individually approved by Apple, developers must either delay their software
updates across all platforms or only update their games on non-iOS platforms, potentially
making the iOS version of the game incompatible with other versions on other platforms until
Apple approves the update. Neither option is tenable for players or developers.
77. Until recently, Apple would have required users to download cloud streaming
software separately for each individual game, install identical app updates for each game
individually, and make repeated trips to Apple’s App Store to find and download games. Apple’s
conduct made cloud streaming apps so unattractive to users that no developer designed one for
the iPhone.
78. Apple undermines cloud gaming apps in other ways too, such as by requiring
cloud games to use Apple’s proprietary payment system and necessitating game overhauls and
payment redesigns specifically for the iPhone. Apple’s rules and restrictions effectively force
developers to create a separate iOS-specific version of their app instead of creating a single
cloud-based version that is compatible with several operating systems, including iOS. As a
result, developers expend considerable time and resources re-engineering apps to bring cross-
platform apps like multiplayer games to the iPhone.
79. Cloud streaming apps broadly speaking—not just gaming—could force Apple to
compete more vigorously against rivals. As one Apple manager recognized, cloud streaming
eliminates “a big reason for high-performance local compute” and thus eliminates one of the
iPhone’s advantages over other smartphones because then “all that matters is who has the
cheapest hardware.” Accordingly, it reduces the need for users to buy expensive phones with
advanced hardware. This problem does not “stop at high-end gaming,” but applies to “a number
of high-compute requirement applications.”
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 34 of 88 PageID: 34
35
B. Apple uses APIs and other critical access points in the smartphone ecosystem
to control the behavior and innovation of third parties in order to insulate
itself from competition
i. Messaging: Apple protects its smartphone monopoly by degrading
and undermining cross-platform messaging apps and rival
smartphones
80. Apple undermines cross-platform messaging to reinforce “obstacle[s] to iPhone
families giving their kids Android phones.” Apple could have made a better cross-platform
messaging experience itself by creating iMessage for Android but concluded that doing so “will
hurt us more than help us.” Apple therefore continues to impede innovation in smartphone
messaging, even though doing so sacrifices the profits Apple would earn from increasing the
value of the iPhone to users, because it helps build and maintain its monopoly power.
81. Messaging apps allow smartphone users to communicate with friends, family, and
other contacts and are often the primary way users interact with their smartphones. In Apple’s
own words, messaging apps are “a central artery through which the full range of customer
experience flows.”
82. Smartphone messaging apps operate using “protocols,” which are the systems that
enable communication and determine the features available when users interact with each other
via messaging apps.
83. One important protocol used by messaging apps is SMS.
1
SMS offers a broad user
network, but limited functionality. For example, all mobile phones can receive SMS messages,
but SMS does not support modern messaging features, such as large files, edited messages, or
reactions like a “thumbs up” or a heart.
1
Following industry practice, throughout this complaint, “SMS” refers to both SMS and MMS (“multimedia
messaging service”). MMS is a companion protocol to SMS that allows for group messages and messages with basic
multimedia content, such as small file sharing.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 35 of 88 PageID: 35
36
84. Many messaging apps—such as WhatsApp, Facebook Messenger, and Signal—
use proprietary, internet-based protocols, which are sometimes referred to as OTT (“over the
top”) protocols. OTT messaging typically involves more secure and advanced features, such as
encryption, typing indicators, read receipts, the ability to share rich media, and disappearing or
ephemeral messages. While all mobile phones can send and receive SMS messages, OTT only
works between users who sign up for and communicate through the same messaging app. As a
result, a user cannot send an OTT message to a friend unless the friend also uses the same
messaging app.
85. Apple makes third-party messaging apps on the iPhone worse generally and
relative to Apple Messages, Apple’s own messaging app. By doing so, Apple is knowingly and
deliberately degrading quality, privacy, and security for its users. For example, Apple designates
the APIs needed to implement SMS as “private,” meaning third-party developers have no
technical means of accessing them and are prohibited from doing so under Apple’s contractual
agreements with developers. As a result, third-party messaging apps cannot combine the “text to
anyone” functionality of SMS with the advanced features of OTT messaging. Instead, if a user
wants to send somebody a message in a third-party messaging app, they must first confirm
whether the person they want to talk to has the same messaging app and, if not, convince that
person to download and use a new messaging app. By contrast, if an Apple Messages user wants
to send somebody a message, they just type their phone number into the “To:” field and send the
message because Apple Messages incorporates SMS and OTT messaging.
86. Apple prohibits third-party developers from incorporating other important
features into their messaging apps as well. For example, third-party messaging apps cannot
continue operating in the background when the app is closed, which impairs functionality like
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 36 of 88 PageID: 36
37
message delivery confirmation. And when users receive video calls, third-party messaging apps
cannot access the iPhone camera to allow users to preview their appearance on video before
answering a call. Apple Messages incorporates these features.
87. If third-party messaging apps could incorporate these features, they would be
more valuable and attractive to users, and the iPhone would be more valuable to Apple in the
short term. For example, by incorporating SMS, users would avoid the hassle of convincing
someone to download a separate app before sending them a message. Third-party messaging
apps could also offer the ability to schedule SMS messages to be sent in the future, suggest
replies, and support robust multi-device use on smartphones, tablets, and computers—as they
have already done on Android.
88. Moreover, messaging apps benefit from significant network effects—as more
people use the app, there are more people to communicate with through the app, which makes
the app more valuable and in turn attracts even more users. Incorporating SMS would help third-
party messaging apps grow their network and attract more users. Instead, Apple limits the reach
of third-party messaging apps and reinforces network effects that benefit Apple.
89. Recently, Apple has stated that it plans to incorporate more advanced features for
cross-platform messaging in Apple Messages by adopting a 2019 version of the RCS protocol
(which combines aspects of SMS and OTT). Apple has not done so yet, and regardless it would
not cure Apple’s efforts to undermine third-party messaging apps because third-party messaging
apps will still be prohibited from incorporating RCS just as they are prohibited from
incorporating SMS. Moreover, the RCS standard will continue to improve over time, and if
Apple does not support later versions of RCS, cross-platform messaging using RCS could soon
be broken on iPhones anyway.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 37 of 88 PageID: 37
38
90. In addition to degrading the quality of third-party messaging apps, Apple
affirmatively undermines the quality of rival smartphones. For example, if an iPhone user
messages a non-iPhone user in Apple Messages—the default messaging app on an iPhone—then
the text appears to the iPhone user as a green bubble and incorporates limited functionality: the
conversation is not encrypted, videos are pixelated and grainy, and users cannot edit messages or
see typing indicators. This signals to users that rival smartphones are lower quality because the
experience of messaging friends and family who do not own iPhones is worse—even though
Apple, not the rival smartphone, is the cause of that degraded user experience. Many non-iPhone
users also experience social stigma, exclusion, and blame for “breaking” chats where other
participants own iPhones. This effect is particularly powerful for certain demographics, like
teenagers—where the iPhone’s share is 85 percent, according to one survey. This social pressure
reinforces switching costs and drives users to continue buying iPhones—solidifying Apple’s
smartphone dominance not because Apple has made its smartphone better, but because it has
made communicating with other smartphones worse.
91. Apple recognizes that its conduct harms users and makes it more difficult to
switch smartphones. For example, in 2013, Apple’s Senior Vice President of Software
Engineering explained that supporting cross-platform OTT messaging in Apple Messages
“would simply serve to remove [an] obstacle to iPhone families giving their kids Android
phones.” In March 2016, Apple’s Senior Vice President of Worldwide Marketing forwarded an
email to CEO Tim Cook making the same point: “moving iMessage to Android will hurt us more
than help us.”
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 38 of 88 PageID: 38
39
92. In 2022, Apple’s CEO Tim Cook was asked whether Apple would fix iPhone-to-
Android messaging. “It’s tough,” the questioner implored Mr. Cook, “not to make it personal but
I can’t send my mom certain videos.” Mr. Cook’s response? “Buy your mom an iPhone.”
93. Recently, Apple blocked a third-party developer from fixing the broken cross-
platform messaging experience in Apple Messages and providing end-to-end encryption for
messages between Apple Messages and Android users. By rejecting solutions that would allow
for cross-platform encryption, Apple continues to make iPhone users’ less secure than they could
otherwise be.
ii. Smartwatches: Apple protects its smartphone monopoly by impeding
the development of cross-platform smartwatches
94. Apple uses smartwatches, a costly accessory, to prevent iPhone customers from
choosing other phones. Having copied the idea of a smartwatch from third-party developers,
Apple now prevents those developers from innovating and limits the Apple Watch to the iPhone
to prevent a negative “impact to iPhone sales.
95. Smartwatches are wrist-worn devices with an interactive display and
accompanying apps that let users perform a variety of functions, including monitoring health
data, responding to messages and notifications, performing mobile payments, and, of course,
telling time. Smartwatches must generally be paired with a smartphone to operate and unlock
their full functionality, such as receiving and responding to emails and text messages or
answering phone calls. Because of the significant cost of buying a smartwatch, users are less
willing to choose a smartphone if it is not compatible with their smartwatch.
96. Apple’s smartwatch—Apple Watch—is only compatible with the iPhone.
So, if Apple can steer a user towards buying an Apple Watch, it becomes more costly for that
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 39 of 88 PageID: 39
40
user to purchase a different kind of smartphone because doing so requires the user to abandon
their costly Apple Watch and purchase a new, Android-compatible smartwatch.
97. By contrast, cross-platform smartwatches can reduce iPhone users’ dependence
on Apple’s proprietary hardware and software. If a user purchases a third-party smartwatch that
is compatible with the iPhone and other smartphones, they can switch from the iPhone to another
smartphone (or vice versa) by simply downloading the companion app on their new phone and
connecting to their smartwatch via Bluetooth. Moreover, as users interact with a smartwatch,
e.g., by accessing apps from their smartwatch instead of their smartphone, users rely less on a
smartphone’s proprietary software and more on the smartwatch itself. This also makes it easier
for users to switch from an iPhone to a different smartphone.
98. Apple recognizes that driving users to purchase an Apple Watch, rather than a
third-party cross-platform smartwatch, helps drive iPhone sales and reinforce the moat around its
smartphone monopoly. For example, in a 2019 email the Vice President of Product Marketing
for Apple Watch acknowledged that Apple Watch “may help prevent iPhone customers from
switching.” Surveys have reached similar conclusions: many users say the other devices linked to
their iPhone are the reason they do not switch to Android.
99. Apple also recognizes that making Apple Watch compatible with Android would
“remove[an] iPhone differentiator.”
100. Apple uses its control of the iPhone, including its technical and contractual
control of critical APIs, to degrade the functionality of third-party cross-platform smartwatches
in at least three significant ways: First, Apple deprives iPhone users with third-party
smartwatches of the ability to respond to notifications. Second, Apple inhibits third-party
smartwatches from maintaining a reliable connection with the iPhone. And third, Apple
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 40 of 88 PageID: 40
41
undermines the performance of third-party smartwatches that connect directly with a cellular
network. In doing so, Apple constrains user choice and crushes innovation that might help fill in
the moat around Apple’s smartphone monopoly.
101. The ability to respond to notifications, e.g., new messages or app alerts, directly
from a smartwatch is one of the top considerations for smartwatch purchasers—and one of the
most used product features when it is available. According to Apple’s own market research, the
ability to “[s]end and receive text messages from social and messaging apps” is a critical feature
for a smartwatch. In 2013, when Apple started offering users the ability to connect their iPhones
with third-party smartwatches, Apple provided third-party smartwatch developers with access to
various APIs related to the Apple Notification Center Service, Calendar, Contacts, and
Geolocation. The following year, Apple introduced the Apple Watch and began limiting third-
party access to new and improved APIs for smartwatch functionality. For example, Apple
prevents third-party smartwatches from accessing APIs related to more advanced Actionable
Notifications, so iPhone users cannot respond to notifications using a third-party smartwatch.
Instead, Apple provides third-party smartwatches access to more limited APIs that do not allow
users to respond to a message, accept a calendar invite, or take other actions available on Apple
Watch.
102. A reliable Bluetooth connection is essential for a smartwatch to connect
wirelessly with a smartphone, and thereby function as a companion to the user’s smartphone and
unlock its full functionality. But Apple prohibits third-party smartwatch developers from
maintaining a connection even if a user accidentally turns off Bluetooth in the iPhone’s control
center. Apple gives its own Apple Watch that functionality, however, because Apple recognizes
that users frequently disable Bluetooth on their iPhone without realizing that doing so
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 41 of 88 PageID: 41
42
disconnects their watch. As a result, iPhone users have a worse experience when they try to use a
third-party smartwatch with their iPhone. Apple also requires users to turn on “Background App
Refresh” and disable the battery-saving “Low Power Mode” in their iPhone settings for third-
party smartwatches to remain consistently connected to their companion app, which is necessary
to allow a user’s iPhone and their smartwatch to update and share data about the weather or
exercise tracking, even though Apple does not impose similar requirements for Apple Watch.
103. Cellular-enabled smartwatches incorporate the ability to connect directly to a
cellular network, allowing users to make calls, send messages, and download data even if their
smartwatch is not paired to a smartphone. Cellular-enabled smartwatches are popular with
consumers, making up approximately 20 percent of Apple Watch sales. Apple Watch users can
use the same phone number for their smartphone and smartwatch when connected to the cellular
network. As a result, messages are delivered to both the user’s smartphone and smartwatch,
providing an integrated messaging experience. Although it is technologically feasible for Apple
to allow an iPhone user with a third-party smartwatch to do the same, Apple instead requires
these users to disable Apple’s iMessage service on the iPhone in order to use the same phone
number for both devices. This is a non-starter for most iPhone users. In practice, iPhone users
with a third-party smartwatch must maintain separate phone numbers for the two devices,
worsening their user experience, and may miss out on receiving messages sent to their primary
iPhone number.
iii. Digital Wallets: Apple restricts cross-platform digital wallets on the
iPhone, reinforcing barriers to consumers switching to rival
smartphones
104. Apple recognizes that paying for products and services with a digital wallet will
eventually become “something people do every day of their lives.” But Apple has used its
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 42 of 88 PageID: 42
43
control over app creation, including its technical and contractual control over API access, to
effectively block third-party developers from creating digital wallets on the iPhone with tap-to-
pay functionality, which is an important feature of a digital wallet for smartphones. As a result,
Apple maintains complete control over how users make tap-to-pay payments with their iPhone.
Apple also deprives users of the benefits and innovations third-party wallets would provide so
that it can protect “Apple’s most important and successful business, iPhone.”
105. Digital wallets are apps that allow a user to store and use passes and credentials,
including credit cards, personal identification, movie tickets, and car keys, in a single app.
For example, digital wallets allow users to make in-person payments by tapping their device on a
payment terminal rather than tapping or swiping a physical credit card. Digital wallets can also
be used for transactions in mobile apps and mobile websites.
106. Absent Apple’s conduct, cross-platform digital wallets could also be used to
manage and pay for subscriptions and in-app purchases.
107. Apple Wallet is Apple’s proprietary digital wallet on the iPhone. Apple Wallet
incorporates Apple’s proprietary payment system Apple Pay, which processes digital payments
on the web, in apps, and at merchant points of sale.
108. Today, Apple Wallet offers users a way to make these payments using their
iPhone. But Apple envisions that Apple Wallet will ultimately supplant multiple functions of
physical wallets to become a single app for shopping, digital keys, transit, identification, travel,
entertainment, and more. As users rely on Apple Wallet for payments and beyond, it “drive[s]
more sales of iPhone and increase[s] stickiness to the Apple ecosystem” because Apple Wallet is
only available on the iPhone. Thus, switching to a different smartphone requires leaving behind
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 43 of 88 PageID: 43
44
the familiarity of an everyday app, setting up a new digital wallet, and potentially losing access
to certain credentials and personal data stored in Apple Wallet.
109. Cross-platform digital wallets would offer an easier, more seamless, and
potentially more secure way for users to switch from the iPhone to another smartphone. For
example, if third-party developers could create cross-platform wallets, users transitioning away
from the iPhone could continue to use the same wallet, with the same cards, IDs, payment
histories, peer-to-peer payment contacts, and other information, making it easier to switch
smartphones. And because many users already use apps created by their preferred financial
institutions, if these financial institutions offered digital wallets, then users would have access to
new apps and technologies without needing to share their private financial data with additional
third parties, including Apple. In the short term, these improved features would make the iPhone
more attractive to users and profitable for Apple.
110. Accordingly, the absence of cross-platform digital wallets with tap-to-pay
capability on the iPhone makes it harder for iPhone users to purchase a different smartphone.
111. The most important function for attracting users to a digital wallet for
smartphones is the ability to offer tap-to-pay, i.e., the ability to make in-person payments by
tapping your smartphone on a payment terminal. Apple uses its control over app creation and
API access to selectively prohibit developers from accessing the near-field communication
(NFC) hardware needed to provide tap-to-pay through a digital wallet app.
112. Apple Wallet is the only app on the iPhone that can use NFC to facilitate tap-to-
pay. While Apple actively encourages banks, merchants, and other parties to participate in Apple
Wallet, Apple simultaneously exerts its smartphone monopoly to block these same partners from
developing better payment products and services for iPhone users.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 44 of 88 PageID: 44
45
113. Apple also uses its smartphone monopoly to extract payments from banks, which
need to access customers that use digital wallets on iPhones. Since Apple first launched Apple
Pay—long before it achieved meaningful adoption—Apple has charged issuing banks 15 basis
points (0.15 percent) for each credit card transaction mediated by Apple Pay. Payment apps from
Samsung and Google are free to issuing banks. Apple’s fees are a significant expense for issuing
banks and cut into funding for features and benefits that banks might otherwise offer smartphone
users. The volume of impacted transactions is large and growing. A U.S. Consumer Financial
Protection Bureau report estimates that Apple Pay facilitated nearly $200 billion in transactions
in the United States in 2022. And the report goes on to explain that “analysts estimate that the
value of digital wallet tap-to-pay transactions will grow by over 150 percent by 2028.”
114. Multiple app developers have sought direct NFC access for their payment or
wallet apps. Yet Apple prohibits these developers from incorporating tap-to-pay functionality in
their apps for fear that doing so would “be one way to disable [A]pple [P]ay trivially,” leading to
the “proliferation of other payment apps” that might operate cross-platform and ultimately
undermine Apple’s smartphone monopoly.
115. There is no technical limitation on providing NFC access to developers seeking to
offer third-party wallets. For example, Apple allows merchants to use the iPhone’s NFC antenna
to accept tap-to-pay payments from consumers. Apple also acknowledges it is technically
feasible to enable an iPhone user to set another app (e.g., a bank’s app) as the default payment
app, and Apple intends to allow this functionality in Europe.
116. Apple further impedes the adoption of digital wallets by restricting others from
offering the same ability to authenticate digital payment options on online checkout pages. By
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 45 of 88 PageID: 45
46
limiting the ability of third-party wallets to provide a simple, fast, and comprehensive solution to
online purchasing, Apple further undermines the viability of such wallets.
117. Apple also blocks other digital wallets from serving as an alternative to Apple’s
in-app payment (IAP). This prevents these wallets from increasing their attractiveness and
improving the overall user experience on the iPhone by offering consumer experiences that may
include use of rewards points in purchasing, digital receipts, returns, loyalty programs, and
digital coupons for purchases of relevant subscriptions and digital goods. Apple even prohibits
developers on its App Store from notifying users in the developer’s app that cheaper prices for
services are available using alternative digital wallets or direct payments.
118. Apple’s conduct reflects its knowing degradation of the experience of its own
users by blocking them from accessing wallets that would have better or different features. In so
doing, Apple cements reliance on the iPhone and also imposes fees on a large and critical slice of
all digital wallet NFC transactions, which the U.S. Consumer Financial Protection Bureau
estimates will grow to $451 billion by 2028.
C. Apple’s “moat” around its smartphone monopoly is wide and deep: it uses a
similar playbook to maintain its monopoly through many other products and
services
119. The exclusionary and anticompetitive acts described above are part of Apple’s
ongoing course of conduct to build and maintain its smartphone monopoly. They are hardly
exhaustive. Rather, they exemplify the innovation Apple has stifled and Apple’s overall strategy
of using its power over app distribution and app creation to selectively block threatening
innovations.
120. Apple has deployed a similar playbook for a much broader range of third-party
apps and services as well, many of which present technologies that function as middleware,
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 46 of 88 PageID: 46
47
facilitate switching, reduce the need for expensive hardware, or disintermediate Apple’s iPhone
by enabling the development of cross-platform technologies. For instance, Apple has
undermined third-party location trackable devices that fully function across platforms. Apple has
impaired third-party, cross-platform video communications apps while steering users to its own
video communication app, FaceTime. Apple has limited the capabilities of third-party iOS web
browsers, including by requiring that they use Apple’s browser engine, WebKit. Protocols that
Apple has placed around new “eSIM” technology may introduce additional frictions for any user
who seeks to transition from an iPhone to a different phone while maintaining the same phone
number. Apple has impeded cross-platform cloud storage apps in order to steer iPhone users into
iCloud, making data transfer between different devices more difficult. Apple uses restrictions in
sales channels to impede the sale and distribution of rival smartphones. And Apple has worsened
its users’ experience by making it difficult for iPhone users to use superior voice and AI
assistants and steering users to use Siri as a voice assistant.
121. Ultimately, the strategies Apple has employed to date are not the only ones Apple
can use to achieve its anticompetitive and lucrative ends. As technology evolves, Apple
continues to evolve and shift its anticompetitive behavior to protect its monopoly power.
For example, in recent years, Apple has increasingly moved into offering its own subscription
services, including news, games, video, music, cloud storage, and fitness subscriptions that could
be used to keep users tethered to the platform. These subscription services and other ancillary
fees are a significant part of Apple’s net revenue. These subscriptions services can also increase
switching costs among iPhone users. If an Apple user can only access their subscription service
on an iPhone, they may experience significant costs, time, lost content, and other frictions if they
attempt to switch to a non-Apple smartphone or subscription service.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 47 of 88 PageID: 47
48
122. These subscription services can also increase Apple’s power over content creators
and newspapers, among others, by exerting control over how audiences access their work,
decreasing traffic to their websites and apps, and positioning Apple as the middleman or
tollbooth operator in the relationship between creators and users. In so doing, Apple takes on
outsize importance and control in the creative economy, which may diminish incentives to fund,
make, and distribute artistic expression.
123. In addition, when one road is closed to Apple, Apple has demonstrated its ability
to find new roads to the same or worse ends. For example, Apple was recently ordered to stop
blocking link-outs by third parties to their websites where users could buy the third party’s
product cheaper. In response, Apple reportedly allowed link-outs to websites but now charges for
purchases made on the web even if they are not an immediate result of a click from a link in a
native iPhone app.
124. Apple has also attempted to undermine cross-platform technologies like digital
car keys in ways that benefit Apple but harm consumers. For example, Apple has required
developers to add digital keys developed for their own apps to Apple Wallet as well. The default
status of Apple Wallet steers users to the Apple Wallet rather than allowing third parties to
present digital car keys only in their own cross-platform app, increasing dependence on Apple
and the iPhone whenever they use their car. At the same time, it decreases the incentives of
automakers to innovate because automakers are forced to share data with Apple and prevented
from differentiating themselves as they could absent Apple’s conduct.
125. Apple’s threatened dominance over the automotive industry goes well beyond the
Apple Wallet and Apple’s demands on car makers to allow innovative products and services on
the iPhone. Apple’s smartphone dominance extends to CarPlay, an Apple infotainment system
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 48 of 88 PageID: 48
49
that enables a car’s central display to serve as a display for the iPhone and enables the driver to
use the iPhone to control maps and entertainment in the car. Like the smartphone market,
infotainment systems are increasingly considered must-have capabilities in newer vehicles. After
leveraging its smartphone dominance to car infotainment systems, Apple has told automakers
that the next generation of Apple CarPlay will take over all of the screens, sensors, and gauges in
a car, forcing users to experience driving as an iPhone-centric experience if they want to use any
of the features provided by CarPlay. Here too, Apple leverages its iPhone user base to exert more
power over its trading partners, including American carmakers, in future innovation. By applying
the same playbook of restrictions to CarPlay, Apple further locks-in the power of the iPhone by
preventing the development of other disintermediating technologies that interoperate with the
phone but reside off device.
V. Anticompetitive Effects
A. Apple’s conduct harms the competitive process
126. As described above, Apple protects its monopoly power in smartphones and
performance smartphones by using its control over app distribution and app creation to suppress
or delay apps, innovations, and technologies that would reduce user switching costs or simply
allow users to discover, purchase, and use their own apps and content without having to rely on
Apple. As a result, Apple faces less competition from rival smartphones and less competitive
pressure from innovative, cross-platform technologies not because Apple makes its own products
better but because it makes other products worse. With the benefit of less competition, Apple
extracts extraordinary profits and regulates innovation to serve its interests. This leaves all
smartphone users worse off, with fewer choices, higher prices and fees, lower quality
smartphones, apps, and accessories, and less innovation from Apple and others. Left
unchallenged, Apple will continue to use and strengthen its smartphone monopoly to dictate how
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 49 of 88 PageID: 49
50
companies can create and distribute apps in the future so that they cannot threaten Apple’s
smartphone monopolies.
127. Apple’s conduct has resulted in less choice for smartphone users. Today, only two
companies (Google and Samsung) remain as meaningful competitors to Apple in the premium
smartphone market.
128. Even when users consider these alternatives, Apple’s conduct has increased the
technical, behavioral, monetary, and other costs of switching from an iPhone to an alternative
smartphone. This undermines competition and entrenches Apple’s monopoly power.
For example, according to user surveys, one of the biggest reasons iPhone users do not switch to
rival smartphones today is to avoid the problems Apple has created for cross-platform
messaging. Likewise, Apple exercised its control over app distribution and app creation to
impede the development and growth of super apps, depriving users of technology that would
have facilitated switching by decreasing user’s dependence on Apple and the iPhone. Apple took
a similar approach to cloud streaming apps, delaying or suppressing technology that would have
made it easier for users to switch to cheaper smartphones. Apple also used its control over app
creation, including its control over critical APIs, to impose technical and contractual restrictions
on messaging apps, third-party smartwatches, and digital wallets, undermining cross-platform
technologies that would have helped users overcome switching costs and friction and ultimately
increased smartphone competition.
129. Apple’s conduct has delayed or suppressed the emergence of cross-platform
technologies that would put competitive pressure on Apple’s ability to extract extraordinary
profits from users and developers. For example, if developers could distribute their programs
through super apps or cloud streaming apps, rather than the App Store, it would put competitive
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 50 of 88 PageID: 50
51
pressure on Apple’s ability to control app distribution and app creation as well as the taxes Apple
imposes on developers who want to distribute apps to iPhone users. Similarly, third-party digital
wallets, or other apps with tap-to-pay functionality, would benefit users and developers by
putting more competitive pressure on Apple as well. For example, digital wallets could
eventually provide developers an alternative way to process payments and manage customer
relationships, forcing Apple to compete more aggressively by lowering fees and improving
quality, which would ultimately benefit users. Instead, Apple continues to exert its power over
customers and financial institutions when users pay for something with their phone—in the App
Store, in an app, or increasingly in the physical world with tap-to-pay.
130. Apple’s conduct has harmed users in other ways. For example, third-party digital
wallets would reduce Apple’s ability to charge banks high fees when users make payments using
Apple Wallet, which ultimately cost consumers through higher prices or other reductions in
quality. Alternative digital wallets could also provide smartphone users better rewards, e.g., cash
back, as well as a more private, secure payment experience from a user’s preferred financial
institution rather than being forced to go through Apple. But these tap-to-pay digital wallet
products and services do not exist today because of Apple.
131. Apple’s conduct has made its own products worse, sacrificing the short-term
profits Apple could earn from improving the iPhone in order to preserve the long-term value of
maintaining its monopoly. In a competitive market, Apple would compete aggressively to
support the development of popular apps and accessories for iPhone users, which would in turn
make iPhones more attractive to users and more valuable. But Apple takes steps to delay or
suppress cross-platform technologies that it recognizes would be popular with users, such as
super apps and cloud streaming apps, because of the threat they pose to Apple’s smartphone
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 51 of 88 PageID: 51
52
monopolies. As a result, several developers have abandoned plans to develop super apps and
cloud-based gaming apps even after making substantial investments in bringing them to market.
Apple’s conduct may have also slowed the development of innovative, high-compute apps
related to education, artificial intelligence, and productivity as well. Apple has also impeded
innovation by third-party smartwatches such that manufacturers have limited the functionality of
their smartwatches for iPhone users, suspended support for iPhone compatibility because of
Apple’s restrictions, or canceled development of cross-platform smartwatches altogether. At
least one company’s canceled smartwatch formed part of its overall wearables strategy, including
future development of virtual-reality technology. Similarly, Apple degrades third-party
messaging apps, even though it makes cross-platform messaging less private and less secure for
iPhone users, because doing so raises switching costs.
132. Apple’s conduct has harmed other smartphone users, too. Because of the
resources and risks required to maintain different features across different smartphones, many
potential super app, mini program, and other developers do not implement features prohibited by
Apple even on other smartphones. For example, prospective digital wallet providers, including
U.S. banks, have abandoned the development of digital-wallet apps for either Apple or other
smartphones. Another company decided not to offer users an innovative digital car key in part
because Apple required that company to add any features related to the key into Apple Wallet
rather than allowing that company to put its key solely in its own app. Other developers have
shrunk, shuttered, or abandoned plans to launch super apps, cloud-streamed gaming apps,
smartwatches, and other apps. As a result, all smartphone users enjoy lower quality smartphones,
less innovation, and less choice.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 52 of 88 PageID: 52
53
133. Apple’s documents and conduct show that Apple is motivated by the
anticompetitive purpose of building or maintaining monopoly power in the relevant markets.
For example, Apple sacrificed substantial revenues it could have earned from super apps, mini
programs, cloud streaming apps, and other third-party apps and accessories. In particular, mobile
gaming already accounts for a large and growing portion of Apple’s revenue. Popular cloud
streamed gaming apps would offer iPhone users access to popular services (including games)
and in turn generate significant revenue for Apple through subscriptions and in-app purchases.
Instead, Apple preferred the long-term benefit of reduced smartphone competition to the revenue
it would generate from cloud gaming, super apps, and mini programs or the quality (and
consumer demand) increase that would flow from this innovation. Apple has also used its control
over app distribution and app creation to selectively undermine cross-platform technologies, not
because this helps protect users but because it helps protect Apple.
134. The harms to smartphone competition caused by Apple’s conduct are amplified
by Apple’s decision to grant itself exclusive distribution rights to iPhone users through the Apple
App Store. If Apple allowed users to access apps in other ways, users could choose an app store
that did not restrict super apps or mini programs, even if Apple ran its App Store the same way it
does today. Apple does not allow that choice, however, because if it did developers could write
their programs for any smartphone rather than specifically for iOS, just as internet browsers and
Apple’s QuickTime allowed developers to write programs that worked on a variety of operating
systems not just Windows. That would lower users’ switching costs and reduce users’ and
developers’ dependence on Apple and the iPhone.
135. Apple’s smartphone monopoly gives it many levers to maintain its power even in
the face of interventions focused on eliminating or disciplining specific anticompetitive
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 53 of 88 PageID: 53
54
practices. This is because Apple’s iPhone monopoly, secured by its anticompetitive conduct,
grants it the power to set the rules by which most smartphone users buy digital and hardware
products, and by which developers are allowed to sell these same products to users. If Apple is
forced to change some of these rules, it has the power to adopt new rules, restrictions, or features
that reinforce Apple’s monopoly and harm competition in other ways. For example, Apple has
stated plans to adopt RCS due to market and international regulatory pressure. But Apple
continues to contractually restrict third parties from accessing other APIs and features that would
enable cross-platform messaging apps. In another instance, Apple was enjoined from enforcing
certain anti-steering provisions in its agreements with developers. In response, Apple simply
created a different set of onerous restrictions on app developers to achieve a similar result. In
other cases, Apple has used its control over app distribution to force companies to comply with
Apple’s policies that may contradict local laws by delaying the review of the offending
companies’ apps.
B. Apple has every incentive to use its monopoly playbook in the future
136. Apple’s conduct does not just impact the past and present but poses significant
risk to the development of new innovations. Apple may use its smartphone monopoly playbook
to acquire or maintain power over next-frontier devices and technologies. As Apple grows its
dominance, Apple may continue delaying or stifling the innovations of cross-platform
companies, in order to lock users into Apple devices.
137. Apple has countless products and services—AirPods, iPads, Music, Apple TV,
photos, maps, iTunes, CarPlay, AirDrop, Apple Card, and Cash. These provide future avenues
for Apple to engage in anticompetitive conduct and the ability to circumvent remedies.
Appropriate forward-looking remedies are necessary to ensure that Apple cannot use these
products and services to further entrench its monopoly power.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 54 of 88 PageID: 54
55
138. Apple’s conduct extends beyond just monopoly profits and even affects the flow
of speech. For example, Apple is rapidly expanding its role as a TV and movie producer and has
exercised that role to control content.
139. Apple has also attempted to use its monopoly to collect user data and stifle
innovation in the automotive industry by, among other things, impeding the development of
digital key technologies by requiring them to be offered in Apple’s proprietary wallet product
and creating new single points of power over emerging uses of the iPhone. These acts further
reinforce Apple’s power in the iPhone by locking in Apple’s services and excluding other
alternative technologies that have the potential to disintermediate Apple’s iPhone.
140. Finally, Apple’s monopolization of smartphone markets gives it tremendous
power over the lives of millions of Americans. Today, Apple uses that power to undermine rival
smartphones, suppress innovative technologies, and stymie consumer choice. Tomorrow, Apple
may use its power to force its own users (and their data) to become its next profitable product.
VI. Privacy, Security, and Other Alleged Countervailing Factors Do Not Justify Apple’s
Anticompetitive Conduct
141. There are no valid, procompetitive benefits of Apple’s exclusionary conduct that
would outweigh its anticompetitive effects. Apple’s moat building has not resulted in lower
prices, higher output, improved innovation, or a better user experience for smartphone users.
142. Apple markets itself on the basis of privacy and security to differentiate itself
from what competition is left in the smartphone market. But this does not justify Apple’s
monopolistic and anticompetitive conduct. Apple imposes contractual restraints on app creation
and distribution, imposes hefty fees on many types of smartphone interactions, and conditionally
restricts API access on its smartphone platform simply because it can. There are limited if any
competitive constraints on this conduct. As a point of comparison, Apple does not engage in
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 55 of 88 PageID: 55
56
such conduct on its Mac laptops and computers. It gives developers the freedom to distribute
software directly to consumers on Mac without going through an Apple-controlled app store and
without paying Apple app store fees. This still provides a safe and secure experience for Mac
users, demonstrating that Apple’s control over app distribution and creation on the iPhone is
substantially more restrictive than necessary to protect user privacy and security.
143. In fact, many alternative technologies that Apple’s conduct suppresses would
enhance user security and privacy. For example, Apple’s conduct targeting digital wallets forces
users to share information with Apple even if they would prefer to share that information solely
with their bank, medical provider, or other trusted third party. In particular, when an iPhone user
provisions a credit or debit card into Apple Wallet, Apple intervenes in a process that could
otherwise occur directly between the user and card issuer introducing an additional point of
failure for privacy and security.
Likewise, super apps or alternative app stores could offer users
and their families a more curated selection of apps that better protect user privacy and security.
Indeed, Apple allows enterprise and public sector customers to offer more curated app stores on
employee iPhones because it better protects privacy and security.
144. Apple is also willing to make the iPhone less secure and less private if that helps
maintain its monopoly power. For example, text messages sent from iPhones to Android phones
are unencrypted as a result of Apple’s conduct. If Apple wanted to, Apple could allow iPhone
users to send encrypted messages to Android users while still using iMessage on their iPhone,
which would instantly improve the privacy and security of iPhone and other smartphone users.
145. Similarly, Apple is willing to sacrifice user privacy and security in other ways so
long as doing so benefits Apple. For example, Apple allows developers to distribute apps
through its App Store that collect vast amounts of personal and sensitive data about users—
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 56 of 88 PageID: 56
57
including children—at the expense of its users’ privacy and security. Apple also enters
agreements to share in the revenue generated from advertising that relies on harvesting users’
personal data. For example, Apple accepts massive payments from Google to set its search
engine as the default in the Safari web browser even though Apple recognizes that other search
engines better protect user privacy.
146. Finally, Apple selectively enforces its rules and contractual restrictions for app
distribution and app creation. For example, when it benefits Apple to do so, Apple permits
developers to introduce mini programs, stream content from the cloud, use virtual currency, and
receive special permissions or access APIs not automatically available to everyone.
147. Ultimately, Apple chooses to make the iPhone private and secure when doing so
benefits Apple; Apple chooses alternative courses when those courses help Apple protect its
monopoly power. Apple’s conduct underscores the pretextual nature of any claim that Apple’s
conduct is justified by protecting user privacy or security.
VII. The Smartphone Industry
A. Background
148. Mobile phones are portable devices that enable communications over radio
frequencies instead of telephone landlines. These signals are transmitted by equipment covering
distinct geographic areas, or “cells,” which is why mobile phones were called cell phones. The
first commercial cell phones became available in the 1980s. Since then, improvements in both
cell phone components and wireless technology have made it possible to transfer large volumes
of data around the globe in a short period. As a result, mobile phones began to offer a wider
array of features and the adoption of mobile phones dramatically increased. Today, nearly all
American adults own a mobile phone.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 57 of 88 PageID: 57
58
149. Smartphones combine the functionality of a traditional mobile phone with
advanced hardware and software components. Smartphones not only make phone calls, but allow
users to listen to music, send text messages, take pictures, play games, access software for work,
manage their finances, and browse the internet. Consumers choose between smartphones based,
in part, on their functionality. Today, smartphone functionality is driven in large part, though not
exclusively, by a combination of hardware and software components. Thus, in a competitive
market, smartphone manufacturers would compete and innovate to provide the best functionality.
150. Although consumers could replace some smartphone functionality with separate
devices such as by always carrying a camera and laptop, they generally prefer to access this
combination of functionality as part of a single device. Thus, phones with some but not all of
these features are not reasonable substitutes for smartphones. For example, a Canon or Nikon
camera is not a substitute for an Apple or Samsung smartphone notwithstanding that both these
products are capable of taking digital pictures.
B. Smartphone Hardware
151. A smartphone’s hardware includes the frame and screen. Higher performing
smartphones are typically constructed from better materials like glass and metal instead of
plastic, manufactured to higher standards that make them more durable (e.g., water and dust
proof), and have higher quality displays.
152. A smartphone’s hardware also includes the semiconductor chipsets that run the
smartphone: central processing of software instructions, graphics, video, display, memory, data
storage, and connection to wireless networks. Chipsets that offer superior performance—faster
processing and network connections, better graphics, more storage—are costly. As a result,
smartphone manufacturers typically include them only in more expensive performance
smartphones.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 58 of 88 PageID: 58
59
153. Smartphone hardware includes other important components like cameras, and
position and motion sensors. Performance smartphones typically have higher quality cameras,
better battery life, wireless charging, and advanced biometrics such as face scanning.
154. Smartphones also contain several types of antennas that allow the phone to
communicate with other smartphones, accessories, or other devices using standard
communication protocols such as Wi-Fi, Bluetooth, and Near-Field Communications (NFC).
a. Wi-Fi is a wireless networking technology that uses radio waves to provide
wireless high-speed Internet access through mobile devices, computers, printers,
and other equipment. “Wi-Fi,” in particular, refers to IEEE 802.11 standards that
define the protocols that enable communications with current Wi-Fi-enabled
wireless devices such as wireless routers and access points.
b. Bluetooth is a wireless standard that allows smartphones to use shortwave radios
to communicate with accessories like headphones and smartwatches. An industry-
wide Bluetooth standard specifies technological requirements to ensure that all
Bluetooth devices can recognize and interact with each other. A typical Bluetooth
signal has a range of about 30 feet.
c. Near Field Communication (NFC) allows smartphones to interact with NFC-
enabled devices like a credit card terminal at a coffee shop. NFC relies on short-
range wireless technologies, including radio signals, to communicate and share
information. To operate, two NFC-enabled devices must typically be within four
centimeters or less of one another.
155. Three device manufacturers, Apple, Samsung, and Google, account for
approximately 94 percent of all smartphones by revenue in the United States. Apple and
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 59 of 88 PageID: 59
60
Samsung alone account for approximately 90 percent of all smartphone revenues in the United
States.
156. Cloud-based technologies are run using hardware and software in remote
computing centers (“the cloud”) rather than by hardware and software on a smartphone. The user
experiences the technology on the phone but the complex computing that generates the rich
experience and that executes the user’s commands happens in the cloud. Thus, cloud apps can
deliver rich experiences on smartphones with less capable hardware than iPhones currently
contain.
C. Smartphone Operating Systems, Applications, and Other Software
157. In addition to hardware, smartphones include various software components that
make a smartphone more attractive to users.
158. The most important software component is a smartphone’s operating system, the
foundational software that manages both the hardware and other software programs on the
device. All iPhones are preloaded with Apple’s proprietary, exclusive iPhone operating system
called iOS. The only other significant mobile operating system in the United States is Google’s
Android, which works with smartphones manufactured by Samsung, whose U.S. headquarters is
located in this district, Google, Motorola, and smaller players. Software applications, known as
“apps,” are programs that perform specific tasks at the smartphone user’s request, such as
sending messages, playing music, or web browsing. Apps depend on a smartphone’s operating
system to function. For example, to make a video call, apps must communicate with a
smartphone’s operating system to access various hardware components on the phone, such as the
camera, microphone, and speaker. Apps communicate with a smartphone’s operating system
through application programming interfaces (APIs).
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 60 of 88 PageID: 60
61
159. Apps that work with a particular smartphone operating system are called native
apps. Thus, Apple’s native iOS apps work with iPhone and native Android apps work with
Android smartphones.
160. Most app developers do not view Android as a substitute for iOS or iOS as a
substitute for Android. The overwhelming majority of users choose a single phone and do not
“multi-home” by carrying an Android phone and the iPhone at the same time. Thus, a developer
cannot reach iPhone users on Android or Android users on iPhones. Due to the lack of user
multi-homing, most developers create native apps for both iOS and Android to reach the greatest
number of smartphone users. For example, a food delivery or ride-sharing app cannot develop an
app just for Android phones or just for the iPhone. Developing for both platforms is often
necessary for developers to reach the scale they need to be viable.
161. It is also important to develop apps for the iPhone and other smartphone platforms
because most apps are increasingly “social” in nature and require users on one platform to reach
users on the other. For example, the developer of a dating app must enable its users on iPhones to
meet users on Android and vice-versa. A money-sharing app must enable users on Android
devices to send money to users on iPhones and vice versa.
162. App developers typically provide a similar user experience for native apps on
iPhones and Android smartphones to minimize the resources and risks of maintaining different
features across different smartphones. Even so, developers must program native apps to work
with a specific operating system and so they do not always interoperate or synchronize across
different operating systems.
163. Middleware is software that provides similar APIs and functionality across a
diverse set of operating systems and devices. This allows developers to create cross-platform
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 61 of 88 PageID: 61
62
applications without having to write separate code for individual operating systems or devices
because developers can rely on the APIs exposed by the middleware rather than APIs that only
work on specific operating systems or devices. Apple has long understood how middleware can
help promote competition and its myriad benefits, including increased innovation and output, by
increasing scale and interoperability. As Apple’s then-Senior Vice President of Software
Engineering testified during the government’s landmark monopolization case in United States v.
Microsoft: “Because we have created QuickTime for both Windows and Macintosh computers,
developers can write a single version of a content product that will run on both Macintosh and
Windows, without the additional expense of ‘porting’ the product to different operating
systems.” In the context of smartphones, examples of middleware include internet browsers,
internet or cloud-based apps, super apps, and smartwatches, among other products and services.
While not meeting the technical definition of middleware, certain other products and services
may nonetheless have the same economic impact as middleware, such as eliminating the added
expense of porting a product or experience across hardware or operating systems. For the
purposes of this complaint middleware refers to both technical middleware and to products and
services that, while not technically middleware, have the same economic effect.
D. Relevant Markets
164. All smartphones compete against each other in a broad relevant market. But
industry participants, including Apple, assess competition among smartphones in narrower
markets that are best understood as submarkets of the larger all-smartphone market. Because
Apple chooses not to compete to sell new smartphones in the entry-level tier, the most relevant
market to assess its conduct is a narrower submarket that excludes this tier. Regardless of how
the market is drawn, however, Apple’s conduct is unlawful.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 62 of 88 PageID: 62
63
iv. Performance smartphones are a relevant product market
165. Performance smartphones are a narrower relevant product market within the
broader smartphone market. This narrower market includes those smartphones that compete with
most iPhones and excludes the lowest-end smartphones, which industry participants sometimes
refer to as “entry-level” smartphones.
166. Industry participants recognize performance smartphones as distinct and
frequently group smartphones into tiers that include entry-level smartphones and higher tiers
such as “premium” or “flagship.”
167. Apple has also long recognized a distinction between these higher-end
smartphones and lower-end, entry-level smartphones. Apple’s own documents indicate it does
not view entry-level smartphones as competing with the iPhone and other performance
smartphones.
168. Performance smartphones have distinct characteristics and uses as compared to
other smartphones. For example, entry-level smartphones are generally made with lower-quality
materials and are less durable (e.g., plastic instead of metal and glass). They have lower-
performance components such as slower processors and lower-capacity storage, which prevent
users from running more intensive applications or storing large volumes of pictures and data on
the device. Entry-level smartphones often lack features such as an NFC antenna that allows
consumers to use their phone to make payments or access passes for public transit.
169. Consumers typically purchase performance smartphones under different terms
than entry-level smartphones. Consumers generally use entry-level smartphones along with pre-
paid service plans. By contrast, consumers usually purchase performance smartphones for use
with post-paid service plans that include promotional discounts to consumers who purchase
performance smartphones.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 63 of 88 PageID: 63
64
170. Because of these differences, among others, between entry-level smartphones and
performance smartphones, entry-level smartphones are not reasonable substitutes for
performance smartphones.
171. Moreover, competition from non-performance smartphones is not sufficient today
to prevent Apple from exercising monopoly power in the performance smartphone market.
v. Smartphones are a broader relevant product market
172. Smartphones are a relevant product market. Smartphones are distinct from phones
that offer less capable hardware and software options than smartphones. These other phones,
sometimes called “feature phones,” may offer basic web browsing in addition to calling and
messaging options, but do not offer the breadth of access to the internet or third-party apps as
smartphones. Similarly, these phones often have lower-quality hardware, such as poorer
displays, less capable cameras, and rely on physical keyboards instead of smartphone touch
screens. Thus, these phones are not reasonable substitutes for smartphones.
173. Smartphones are also distinct from other portable devices, such as tablets,
smartwatches, and laptop computers. These devices lack the combination of function, size, and
portability that consumers rely on in a smartphone, even if they offer some similar capabilities.
Thus, none of these other products are reasonable substitutes for smartphones.
174. Apple, other participants in the market, and the public recognize that smartphones
are distinct from feature phones and other portable devices.
175. Competition from feature phones, or other alternatives, is not sufficient to prevent
Apple from exercising monopoly power in the smartphone market.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 64 of 88 PageID: 64
65
vi. The United States is a relevant geographic market for performance
smartphones and smartphones
176. The United States is a relevant geographic market for the sale of performance
smartphones and smartphones. Users in the United States demand services offered by U.S.
retailers when they purchase a smartphone. For example, consumers who purchase a smartphone
from their mobile carrier can get assistance with activating their new device, setting it up, and
transferring important content like apps, messages, photos, and video to their new smartphone. A
smartphone purchased abroad for use in the United States might be incompatible with the
consumer’s domestic carrier, may not have the necessary radio technology to take advantage of
the carrier’s highest speed connections, the carrier might not be able to offer support during setup
or subsequently, or the phone’s warranty may be invalid.
177. Consumers must also purchase smartphones through a U.S. retailer if they want to
take advantage of valuable promotions offered by their mobile carrier. These same promotions
and free financing are unavailable to U.S. consumers who purchase their phones in other
countries.
178. Finally, potential new smartphone entrants to the U.S. market must also comply
with telecommunications regulations and satisfy other legal requirements. No extensive
regulatory framework governs how Apple operates its platform with respect to developers, but
there are a number of regulatory requirements that must be met in order to enter the smartphone
market. For example, some smartphone makers are effectively barred from offering their
smartphones to U.S. consumers.
179. Consumers in the United States could not avoid or defeat an increase in the price
of performance smartphones or smartphones by purchasing and importing smartphones from
abroad. This allows Apple to set prices for the same smartphone in the United States separately
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 65 of 88 PageID: 65
66
from those in other countries. For example, Apple lowered the price of the iPhone 11 in China
relative to the United States because Apple faced greater competition in China. This additional
competition arises in part because a popular super app put competitive pressure on Apple and
made it easier for users to switch from an iPhone to a rival smartphone. As a result, Apple is
unable to command the same prices for the iPhone in China than they do in the United States due
to less competition.
E. Apple has monopoly power in the smartphone and performance smartphone
markets
180. Apple has monopoly power in the smartphone and performance smartphone
markets because it has the power to control prices or exclude competition in each of them. Apple
also enjoys substantial and durable market shares in these markets. Moreover, Apple’s market
shares likely underestimate Apple’s power because they are protected by significant barriers to
entry, network effects, and switching costs. Apple recognizes and exploits these barriers to entry,
network effects, and switching costs to protect itself from competition from rival platforms and
innovations, products, and services that may diminish consumer reliance on the iPhone. Apple’s
power will likely increase over time.
181. In the U.S. market for performance smartphones, where Apple views itself as
competing, Apple estimates its market share exceeds 70 percent. These estimates likely
understate Apple’s market share today. For example, Apple’s share among key demographics,
including younger audiences and higher-income households, is even larger. Even in the broadest
market consisting of all smartphones—including many smartphones that Apple and industry
participants do not view as competing with Apple’s iPhones and other higher-end phones—
Apple’s share is more than 65 percent by revenue. Similarly, even if consumers choose one
phone over another, the vast majority of developers consider iPhones and Android devices as
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 66 of 88 PageID: 66
67
complements because developers must build apps that run on both platforms due to the lack of
user multi-homing. In effect, the lack of multi-homing among users necessitates multi-homing
among developers. This market reality increases the power that Apple is able to exercise over
developers that seek to reach users on smartphones—especially performance smartphones that
run sophisticated apps.
182. Apple’s high market shares are durable. Over the last decade, Apple increased its
share of smartphones sold in the United States most years. Through the same period, Apple
collected more than half the revenue for all smartphones sold in the United States.
183. Apple’s monopoly power in the relevant markets is protected by substantial
barriers to entry and expansion. For example, since fewer than ten percent of smartphone
purchasers in the United States are buying their first smartphone, there are fewer new customers
available for Apple’s rivals. Instead, rivals must encourage existing iPhone users to switch from
using an iPhone to using another smartphone when they replace or upgrade their phone. As a
result, switching costs—many created or exacerbated by Apple—impose substantial barriers to
entry and expansion for rival smartphones. This barrier is increasingly impenetrable. Nearly 90
percent of iPhone owners in the United States replace their iPhone with another iPhone. At least
one U.S. carrier estimates that as high as 98 percent of iPhone users on its network replace or
upgrade their iPhone in a given quarter by buying another iPhone. The increased switching costs
that consumers experience because of Apple’s conduct underpins these exceedingly high
retention rates.
184. Apple’s monopoly power in the relevant markets is protected by other barriers to
entry, expansion, or repositioning as well. For example, introducing a new smartphone requires
considerable investments in acquiring expensive and scarce components such as mobile chips
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 67 of 88 PageID: 67
68
and specialized glass for screens. Other significant barriers to entry include product design,
software development, regulatory approval, manufacturing, marketing, and customer service.
Because most smartphones are bought through mobile carriers including Verizon, which has its
operations headquarters in this district, new entrants or those seeking to expand or reposition
must meet the carriers’ technical requirements to access the major carrier networks in the United
States. New entrants and smaller rivals must also negotiate distribution agreements and persuade
carriers and other retailers to promote their products to consumers. As explained above, rival
smartphones must also overcome the substantial network effects generated by interactions
between users, developers, and others who interact with the iPhone.
185. Apple’s iPhone platform is protected by several additional barriers to entry and
expansion, including strong network and scale effects and high switching costs and frictions. For
example, if an iPhone user wants to buy an Android smartphone, they are likely to face
significant financial, technological, and behavioral obstacles to switching. The user may need to
re-learn how to operate their smartphone using a new interface, transfer large amounts of data
(e.g., contacts), purchase new apps, or transfer or buy new subscriptions and accessories. These
switching costs and frictions are even higher when software applications, APIs, and other
functionality do not help the different devices and operating systems communicate and
interoperate. These switching costs and frictions increase the “stickiness” of the iPhone, making
users more beholden to the smartphone manufacturer and platform operator.
186. Many prominent, well-financed companies have tried and failed to successfully
enter the relevant markets because of these entry barriers. Past failures include Amazon (which
released its Fire mobile phone in 2014 but could not profitably sustain its business and exited the
following year); Microsoft (which discontinued its mobile business in 2017); HTC (which exited
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 68 of 88 PageID: 68
69
the market by selling its smartphone business to Google in September 2017); and LG (which
exited the smartphone market in 2021). Today, only Samsung and Google remain as meaningful
competitors in the U.S. performance smartphone market. Barriers are so high that Google is a
distant third to Apple and Samsung despite the fact that Google controls development of the
Android operating system.
187. Apple’s monopoly power is separately demonstrated by direct indicia. For
example, Apple can and does profitably forego innovation without fear of losing customers to
competitors. For example, Apple’s vice president of iPhone marketing explained in February
2020: “In looking at it with hindsight, I think going forward we need to set a stake in the ground
for what features we think are ‘good enough’ for the consumer. I would argue were [sic] already
doing *more* than what would have been good enough.”
After identifying old features that
“would have been good enough today if we hadn’t introduced [updated features] already,” she
explained, “anything new and especially expensive needs to be rigorously challenged before it’s
allowed into the consumer phone.”
188. Apple’s profits and profit margins, for nearly every aspect of the iPhone, are
further evidence of Apple’s monopoly power. For example, Apple’s per-unit smartphone profit
margins are far more than its next most profitable rival. Apple charges carriers considerably
more than its rivals to buy and resell its smartphones to the public and employs contract clauses
that may impede the ability of carriers to promote rival smartphones, a harmful exercise of
monopoly power that is hidden to most consumers. Apple extracts fees from developers—as
much as 30 percent when users purchase apps or make in-app payments. Apple also extracts a
0.15 percent commission from banks on credit card transactions through its digital wallet, while
none of its smartphone competitors with digital wallets charge any fee. Apple predicts that it will
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 69 of 88 PageID: 69
70
collect nearly $1 billion in worldwide revenue on Apple Pay fees by 2025.
A recent report by the
U.S. Consumer Financial Protection Bureau suggest these revenues will only increase, as
“analysts expect the value of digital wallet tap-to-pay transactions will grow by over 150 percent
by 2028.”
189. Apple increasingly charges developers additional fees to promote their apps in the
App Store as well. In fact, this is one of the fastest-growing parts of Apple’s services business,
with revenue “increasing by more than a third to $4.4B in FY 2022.”
190. These indicia of Apple’s monopoly power are direct evidence of its monopoly
power in the relevant markets.
VIII. Jurisdiction, Venue, and Commerce
191. The United States brings this action pursuant to Section 4 of the Sherman Act, 15
U.S.C § 4, to prevent and restrain Apple’s violations of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.
§ 2.
192. The Attorneys General assert these claims based on their independent authority to
bring this action pursuant to Section 16 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 26, and common law, to
obtain injunctive and other equitable relief based upon Apple’s anticompetitive practices in
violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2.
193. The Attorneys General are the chief legal officers of their respective states. They
have authority to bring actions to protect the economic wellbeing of their states and residents,
and to seek injunctive relief to remedy and protect against harm resulting from violations of the
antitrust laws.
194. Apple’s actions and course of conduct are ongoing and are likely to continue or
recur, including through other practices with the same purpose or effect.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 70 of 88 PageID: 70
71
195. Apple’s actions complained of herein have harmed, and continue to harm,
competition, consumers, and the general welfare and economies of the Plaintiff States. This
Court has subject matter jurisdiction over this action under Section 4 of the Sherman Act, 15
U.S.C. § 4, and 28 U.S.C. §§ 1331, 1337(a), and 1345.
196. The Court has personal jurisdiction over Apple, and venue is proper in this
District under Section 12 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 22, and under 28 U.S.C. § 1391,
because Apple transacts business and is found within this District.
197. Apple is a corporation headquartered in Cupertino, California. Apple is one of the
largest publicly traded companies in the world, generating hundreds of billions of dollars from
the sale of smartphones, computers, tablets, and related services and accessories.
198. Apple engages in, and its activities substantially affect, interstate trade and
commerce. Apple provides a range of products and services that are marketed, distributed, and
offered to consumers throughout the United States, in the plaintiff States, across state lines, and
internationally.
IX. Violations Alleged
A. First Claim for Relief: Monopolization of the Performance Smartphone
Market in the United States in Violation of Sherman Act § 2
199. Plaintiffs incorporate the allegations of paragraphs 1 through 198 above.
200. Performance smartphones in the United States is a relevant antitrust market, and
Apple has monopoly power in that market.
201. Apple has willfully monopolized the performance smartphone market in the
United States through an exclusionary course of conduct and the anticompetitive acts described
herein. Each of Apple’s actions individually and collectively increased, maintained, or protected
its performance smartphone monopoly.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 71 of 88 PageID: 71
72
202. Apple’s anticompetitive acts include, but are not limited to, its contractual
restrictions against app creation, distribution, and access to APIs that have impeded apps and
technologies including, but not limited to, super apps, cloud streaming, messaging, wearables,
and digital wallets. The areas identified in this complaint reflect a non-exhaustive list of recent
anticompetitive acts but as technology advances, both the technologies impeded and the specific
manner of impediment may shift in response to technological and regulatory change consistent
with Apple’s past conduct.
203. While each of Apple’s acts is anticompetitive in its own right, Apple’s
interrelated and interdependent actions have had a cumulative and self-reinforcing effect that has
harmed competition and the competitive process. Apple’s anticompetitive acts have had harmful
effects on competition and consumers.
204. Apple’s exclusionary conduct lacks a procompetitive justification that offsets the
harm caused by Apple’s anticompetitive and unlawful conduct.
B. Second Claim for Relief, in the Alternative: Attempted Monopolization of the
Performance Smartphone Market in the United States in Violation of
Sherman Act § 2
205. Plaintiffs incorporate the allegations of paragraphs 1 through 204 above.
206. Performance smartphones in the United States is a relevant antitrust market, and
Apple has attempted to monopolize that market.
207. Apple has attempted to monopolize the performance smartphone market in the
United States through an exclusionary course of conduct and the anticompetitive acts described
herein. Each of Apple’s actions individually and collectively increased Apple’s market power in
the performance smartphone market.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 72 of 88 PageID: 72
73
208. Apple’s anticompetitive acts include, but are not limited to, its contractual
restrictions against app creation, distribution, and access to APIs that have impeded apps and
technologies including, but not limited to, super apps, cloud streaming, messaging, wearables,
and digital wallets. The areas identified in this complaint reflect a non-exhaustive list of recent
anticompetitive acts but as technology advances, both the technologies impeded and the specific
manner of impediment may shift in response to technological and regulatory change consistent
with Apple’s past conduct.
209. While each of Apple’s acts is anticompetitive in its own right, Apple’s
interrelated and interdependent actions have had a cumulative and self-reinforcing effect that has
harmed competition and the competitive process.
210. In undertaking this course of conduct, Apple has acted with specific intent to
monopolize, and to destroy effective competition in, the performance smartphone market in the
United States. There is a dangerous probability that, unless restrained, Apple will succeed in
monopolizing the performance smartphone market in the United States, in violation of Section 2
of the Sherman Act.
C. Third Claim for Relief: Monopolization of the Smartphone Market in the
United States in Violation of Sherman Act § 2
211. Plaintiffs incorporate the allegations of paragraphs 1 through 210 above.
212. Smartphones in the United States is a relevant antitrust market, and Apple has
monopoly power in that market.
213. Apple has willfully monopolized the smartphone market in the United States
through an exclusionary course of conduct and the anticompetitive acts described herein. Each of
Apple’s actions individually and collectively increased, maintained, or protected its smartphone
monopoly.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 73 of 88 PageID: 73
74
214. Apple’s anticompetitive acts include, but are not limited to, its contractual
restrictions against app creation, distribution, and access to APIs that have impeded apps and
technologies including, but not limited to, super apps, cloud streaming, messaging, wearables,
and digital wallets. The areas identified in this complaint reflect a non-exhaustive list of recent
anticompetitive acts but as technology advances, both the technologies impeded and the specific
manner of impediment may shift in response to technological and regulatory change consistent
with Apple’s past conduct.
215. While each of Apple’s acts is anticompetitive in its own right, Apple’s
interrelated and interdependent actions have had a cumulative and self-reinforcing effect that has
harmed competition and the competitive process.
216. Apple’s anticompetitive acts have had harmful effects on competition and
consumers.
217. Apple’s exclusionary conduct lacks a procompetitive justification that offsets the
harm caused by Apple’s anticompetitive and unlawful conduct.
D. Fourth Claim for Relief, in the Alternative: Attempted Monopolization of the
Smartphone Market in the United States in Violation of Sherman Act § 2
218. Plaintiffs incorporate the allegations of paragraphs 1 through 217 above.
219. Smartphones in the United States is a relevant antitrust market, and Apple has
attempted to monopolize that market.
220. Apple has attempted to monopolize the smartphone market in the United States
through an exclusionary course of conduct and the anticompetitive acts described herein. Each of
Apple’s actions individually and collectively increased Apple’s market power in the smartphone
market.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 74 of 88 PageID: 74
75
221. Apple’s anticompetitive acts include, but are not limited to, its contractual
restrictions against app creation, distribution, and access to APIs that have impeded apps and
technologies including, but not limited to, super apps, cloud streaming, messaging, wearables,
and digital wallets. The areas identified in this complaint reflect a non-exhaustive list of recent
anticompetitive acts but as technology advances, both the technologies impeded and the specific
manner of impediment may shift in response to technological and regulatory change consistent
with Apple’s past conduct.
222. While each of Apple’s acts is anticompetitive in its own right, Apple’s
interrelated and interdependent actions have had a cumulative and self-reinforcing effect that has
harmed competition and the competitive process.
223. In undertaking this course of conduct, Apple has acted with specific intent to
monopolize, and to destroy effective competition in, the smartphone market in the United States.
There is a dangerous probability that, unless restrained, Apple will succeed in monopolizing the
smartphone market in the United States, in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
E. Fifth Claim for Relief: Violation of the New Jersey Antitrust Act (Monopoly
Maintenance)
224. Plaintiff State of New Jersey repeats and realleges and incorporates by reference
each and every preceding paragraph and allegation of this Complaint as if fully set forth herein.
225. The New Jersey Antitrust Act, N.J.S.A. 56:9-4(a), states: “It shall be unlawful for
any person to monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or to combine or conspire with any person
or persons, to monopolize trade or commerce in any relevant market within this State.”
226. In the operation of its business, Apple engaged in numerous commercial
practices that violate the New Jersey Antitrust Act, N.J.S.A. 56:9-1 to -19, including
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 75 of 88 PageID: 75
76
monopolizing or attempting to monopolize trade or commerce in the smartphone market and the
performance smartphone market within the State of New Jersey, in violation of N.J.S.A. 56:9-4.
227. Each violation of the New Jersey Antitrust Act by Apple constitutes a separate
unlawful practice and violation, under N.J.S.A. 56:9-16.
228. Plaintiff State of New Jersey seeks all remedies available under the New Jersey
Antitrust Act, N.J.S.A. 56:9-1 to -19, including, without limitation, the following: (a) injunctive
and other equitable relief, pursuant to N.J.S.A. 56:9-7 and N.J.S.A.56:9-10(a); and (b) other
remedies as the Court may deem appropriate and the interests of justice may require.
F. Sixth Claim for Relief: Violations of Wisconsin State Law
229. Plaintiff State of Wisconsin repeats and re-alleges and incorporates by reference
every paragraph and allegation in this Complaint as if fully set forth herein.
230. The aforementioned practices by Apple violate Wisconsin’s Antitrust Act, Wis.
Stat. Ch. § 133.03 et seq. These violations substantially affect the people of Wisconsin and have
impacts within the State of Wisconsin.
231. Plaintiff State of Wisconsin, through its Attorney General and under its antitrust
enforcement authority in Wis. Stat. Ch. 133, is entitled to all remedies available under Wis. Stat.
§§ 133.03, 133.16, 133.17, and 133.18.
X. Request for Relief
232. To remedy these illegal acts, Plaintiffs request that the Court:
1. Adjudge and decree that Apple has acted unlawfully to monopolize, or, in the
alternative, attempt to monopolize, the smartphone market in the United States
in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2;
2. Adjudge and decree that Apple has acted unlawfully to monopolize, or, in the
alternative, attempt to monopolize, the performance smartphone market in the
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 76 of 88 PageID: 76
77
United States in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, the
New Jersey Antitrust Act, N.J.S.A. 56:9-1 to -19, Wisconsin’s Antitrust Act,
Wis. Stat. Ch. § 133.03 et seq.;
3. Enter relief as needed to cure any anticompetitive harm;
4. Enjoin Apple from continuing to engage in the anticompetitive practices
described herein and from engaging in any other practices with same purpose
or effect as the challenged practices, including but not limited to:
a. preventing Apple from using its control of app distribution to
undermine cross-platform technologies such as super apps and
cloud streaming apps, among others;
b. preventing Apple from using private APIs to undermine cross-
platform technologies like messaging, smartwatches, and digital
wallets, among others; and
c. preventing Apple from using the terms and conditions of its
contracts with developers, accessory makers, consumers, or others
to obtain, maintain, extend, or entrench a monopoly.
5. Enter any other preliminary or permanent relief necessary and appropriate to
restore competitive conditions in the markets affected by Apple’s unlawful
conduct;
6. Enter any additional relief the Court finds just and proper; and
7. Award each Plaintiff, as applicable, an amount equal to its costs, including
reasonable attorneys’ fees, incurred in bringing this action.
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 77 of 88 PageID: 77
78
Dated: March 21, 2024
R
espectfull
y
,
FOR PLAINTIFF UNITED STATES OF AMERICA:
JONATHAN S. KANTER
Assistant Attorney General for Antitrust
DOHA G. MEKKI
Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General
for Antitrust
HETAL J. DOSHI
Deputy Assistant Attorney General for
Antitrust
MICHAEL B. KADES
Deputy Assistant Attorney General for
Antitrust
RYAN DANKS
Director of Civil Enforcement
MIRIAM R. VISHIO
Deputy Director of Civil Enforcement
ERIC D. DUNN
Counsel to the Assistant Attorney General
DANIEL S. GUARNERA
Chief, Civil Conduct Task Force
JACKLIN CHOU LEM
Civil Chief, San Francisco Office
KATE M. RIGGS
Assistant Chief, Civil Conduct Task Force
PHILIP R. SELLINGER
United States Attorney
s/ J. Andrew Ruymann
By: J. ANDREW RUYMANN*
Assistant United States Attorney
U.S. Attorney’s Office
402 East State Street, Room 430
Trenton, NJ 08608
Telephone: 609-989-0563
s/ Jonathan Lasken
By: JONATHAN LASKEN*
Assistant Chief, Civil Conduct Task Force
LORRAINE VAN KIRK
Senior Litigation Counsel
s/ Jennifer Hane
By: JENNIFER HANE
SEAN CARMAN
PAM COLE
JAMES ROBERT DUNCAN III
JEREMY C. KEENEY
ANDREW L. KLINE
PATRICK M. KUHLMANN
MATTHEW C. MANDELBERG
NOLAN J. MAYTHER
MICHAEL MIKAWA
SARAH OLDFIELD
MICHAEL A. RABKIN
AARON M. SHEANIN
MICAH D. STEIN
JESSICA JOHNSTON TATICCHI
Trial Attorneys
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 78 of 88 PageID: 78
79
United States Department of Justice
Antitrust Division
450 Fifth Street NW, Suite 8600
Washington, DC 20530
Telephone: 202-598-6517
Attorneys for the United States
*Attorne
y
s of Recor
d
FOR PLAINTIFF STATE OF NEW JERSEY
:
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 79 of 88 PageID: 79
80
FOR PLAINTIFF STATE THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA:
BRIAN L. SCHWALB
ATTORNEY GENERAL
JENNIFER C. JONES
Deputy Attorney General
Public Advocacy Division
BETH MELLEN
WILLIAM F. STEPHENS
Assistant Deputy Attorneys General
Public Advocacy Division
ADAM GITLIN
Chief, Antitrust and Nonprofit Enforcement Section
Public Advocacy Division
ELIZABETH G. ARTHUR
Assistant Attorney General
Public Advocacy Division
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 80 of 88 PageID: 80
81
400 6th Street NW, 10th Floor
Washington, D.C. 20001
Tel.: 202-442-9864
Attorneys for Plaintiff State the District of Columbia
Pro hac vice application forthcoming
FOR PLAINTIFF STATE OF MAINE:
AARON M. FREY
Attorney General of Maine
______________________
CHRISTINA M. MOYLAN
Assistant Attorney General
MICHAEL DEVINE
Assistant Attorney General
Consumer Protection Division
Office of the Maine Attorney General
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 81 of 88 PageID: 81
82
6 State House Station
Augusta, ME 04333-0006
Telephone: 207-626-8800
Attorneys for Plaintiff State of Maine
Pro hac vice application forthcoming
FOR PLAINTIFF PEOPLE OF THE STATE OF MICHIGAN:
DANA NESSEL
Attorney General of Michigan
JASON R. EVANS
Division Chief
Corporate Oversight Division
SCOTT A. MERTENS
Section Head
Corporate Oversight Division
JONATHAN S. COMISH
Assistant Attorney General
Corporate Oversight Division
LEANN D. SCOTT
Assistant Attorney General
Corporate Oversight Division
Michigan Department of Attorney General
525 W Ottawa St.
Lansing, MI 48933
Telephone: 517-335-7622
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 82 of 88 PageID: 82
83
Attorneys for Plaintiff People of the State of Michigan
Pro hac vice application forthcoming
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 83 of 88 PageID: 83
84
FOR PLAINTIFF STATE OF NEW HAMPSHIRE:
By its attorney,
JOHN M. FORMELLA
Attorney General
________________________
ALEXANDRA C. SOSNOWSKI
Assistant Attorney General
Consumer Protection and Antitrust Bureau
New Hampshire Department of Justice
Office of the Attorney General
One Granite Place South
Concord, NH 03301
Telephone: 603-271-2678
Attorneys for Plaintiff State of New Hampshire
Pro hac vice application forthcoming
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 84 of 88 PageID: 84
85
FOR PLAINTIFF STATE OF NORTH DAKOTA:
DREW H. WRIGLEY
Attorney General
State of North Dakota
Elin S. Alm
Assistant Attorney General
Christopher G. Lindblad
Assistant Attorney General
Consumer Protection and Antitrust Division
Office of Attorney General
1720 Burlington Drive, Suite C
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 85 of 88 PageID: 85
86
Bismarck, ND 58504-7736
Telephone: 701-328-5570
Attorneys for Plaintiff State of North Dakota
Pro hac vice application forthcoming
FOR PLAINTIFF STATE OF OKLAHOMA:
GENTNER DRUMMOND
Attorney General of Oklahoma
CALEB J. SMITH
Assistant Attorney General
Consumer Protection Unit
Office of the Oklahoma Attorney General
15 West 6th Street
Suite 1000
Tulsa, OK 74119
Telephone: 918-581-2230
Attorneys for Plaintiff State of Oklahoma
Pro hac vice application forthcoming
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 86 of 88 PageID: 86
87
FOR PLAINTIFF STATE OF WISCONSIN:
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 87 of 88 PageID: 87
88
Case 2:24-cv-04055 Document 1 Filed 03/21/24 Page 88 of 88 PageID: 88